2019
DOI: 10.1177/0743915619845424
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Reducing Obesity by Taxing Soft Drinks: Tax Salience and Firms’ Strategic Responses

Abstract: In the fight against obesity, governments have pursued various policies to increase soda prices in the hope of discouraging consumption. Previous studies examining the efficacy of taxing sodas have generalized sales taxes to other taxes and assumed that imposing a tax is as salient as imposing a direct price hike. In this research, the authors recognize that most consumers do not pay much attention to how taxes differ in application. Thus, the authors disassociate the effects of sales taxes from the effects of… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 8 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 51 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…3 As we discuss later, the tax did not apply to SSBs that have 25 calories or fewer per 12 ounces nor chocolate milk. 4 Although not the goal here, several papers specifically examine tax pass-through across different types of taxes (ad valorem vs. specific) and market structures in both theoretical and empirical settings (Allcott et al, 2019;Anderson et al, 2001;Bonnet & Réquillart, 2013;Delipalla & Keen, 1992;Weyl & Fabinger, 2013;Zheng et al, 2019). These papers provide guidance not only on the conditions which yield low versus high tax pass-though (including over-shifting) but also on the design of optimal tax policies.…”
Section: Data Availability Statementmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…3 As we discuss later, the tax did not apply to SSBs that have 25 calories or fewer per 12 ounces nor chocolate milk. 4 Although not the goal here, several papers specifically examine tax pass-through across different types of taxes (ad valorem vs. specific) and market structures in both theoretical and empirical settings (Allcott et al, 2019;Anderson et al, 2001;Bonnet & Réquillart, 2013;Delipalla & Keen, 1992;Weyl & Fabinger, 2013;Zheng et al, 2019). These papers provide guidance not only on the conditions which yield low versus high tax pass-though (including over-shifting) but also on the design of optimal tax policies.…”
Section: Data Availability Statementmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Following previous structural models on SSB taxes [ 26 , 32 , 33 ], we implement a random-coefficients logit demand model [ 34 , 35 ]. The indirect utility function for household i ∈(1,…, H ) when consuming beverage j from the choice set j ∈(0,…, J ) at market t ∈(1,…, T ) is: where Sugar j is beverage j ’s sugar content in terms of grams per liter, and p jt is beverage j ’s price per liter at market t .…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For sensitivity analyses of the demand model, we use 2,000 and 5,000 draws of households’ characteristics for Eq ( 3 ) to test for the precision of the estimated coefficients. Moreover, we also re-run the demand model including seasonal dummies following the equivalent approach in the studies by Zheng et al [ 33 ] and Liu et al [ 41 ]. Finally, we extend the set of instruments by including average monthly prices of beverage j in cities that are not part of Nielsen CPS and correspond to urban locations from which INEGI [ 31 ] collects price information to calculate the consumer price index.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Following previous structural models on SSB taxes [26,32,33], we implement a random-coefficients logit demand model [34,35]. The indirect utility function for household i2(1,. .…”
Section: Demand Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%