2014
DOI: 10.3982/ecta10528
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

Abstract: A wide body of empirical evidence finds that approximately 25 percent of fiscal stimulus payments (e.g., tax rebates) are spent on nondurable household consumption in the quarter that they are received. To interpret this fact, we develop a structural economic model where households can hold two assets: a low-return liquid asset (e.g., cash, checking account) and a high-return illiquid asset that carries a transaction cost (e.g., housing, retirement account). The optimal life-cycle pattern of portfolio choice i… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

3
64
1
1

Year Published

2018
2018
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
2
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 597 publications
(69 citation statements)
references
References 97 publications
(106 reference statements)
3
64
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Much of the recent theoretical work on MPCs has focused on rationalizing the existence of high-MPC households. For example, Kaplan and Violante (2014) and Carroll et al (2017) show that calibrated models with liquidity constraints and preferences exhibiting prudence can yield households with reasonably high MPCs through (i) precautionary savings, which generate a steep consumption function for lower wealth individuals, and (ii) binding liquidity constraints, which render some households "hand-to-mouth. "…”
Section: Near Zeromentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Much of the recent theoretical work on MPCs has focused on rationalizing the existence of high-MPC households. For example, Kaplan and Violante (2014) and Carroll et al (2017) show that calibrated models with liquidity constraints and preferences exhibiting prudence can yield households with reasonably high MPCs through (i) precautionary savings, which generate a steep consumption function for lower wealth individuals, and (ii) binding liquidity constraints, which render some households "hand-to-mouth. "…”
Section: Near Zeromentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In contrast, simple permanent income hypothesis models imply that consumption should be much smoother than income. Two potential remedies are pervasive liquidity constraints (e.g., Kaplan and Violante (2014)) or very persistent income shocks, both of which closely tie consumption to current income (vs. permanent income).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This specification levers the cross-sectional information contained in our international data set to generalize a similar model that we estimated in Del Negro et al (2017) on data for the United States. One possible interpretation of the γ trends is that they reflect the growth rate of consumption of households that are hand-to-mouth or liquidity constrained (Campbell and Mankiw, 1989;Kaplan and Violante, 2014) and/or are excluded from international asset markets, as in the limited-participation literature (e.g., Vissing-Jorgensen, 2002).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is likely due to the fact that composition of the corporate bond indexes in terms of credit ratings, liquidity, and maturity is different relative to the U.S. 33 Table A1 in the Appendix provides more details on the posterior distribution of the decline in the world real interest rate and in the factors that drive it. the γ trends is that they reflect the growth rate of consumption of households that are hand-to-mouth or liquidity constrained (Campbell and Mankiw, 1989;Kaplan and Violante, 2014) and/or are excluded from international asset markets, as in the limited-participation literature (e.g., Vissing-Jorgensen, 2002).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%