2000
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.244573
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A Theory of Trade Secrets in Firms

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
25
0

Year Published

2003
2003
2011
2011

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 17 publications
(25 citation statements)
references
References 30 publications
0
25
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We capture this asymmetry by assuming that offers can be made only by informed agents. 12 1 0 For other papers that relate the possibility of employees' defection to the distribution of wages within the Þrm, see Stole and Zweibel (1994), Wolinsky (2000) and Zabojnik (2000). In particular, Zabojnik (2000) explores how hierarchical Þrms pay employees efficiency wages in accordance with the potential threat of their leaving the Þrm with relevant information.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…We capture this asymmetry by assuming that offers can be made only by informed agents. 12 1 0 For other papers that relate the possibility of employees' defection to the distribution of wages within the Þrm, see Stole and Zweibel (1994), Wolinsky (2000) and Zabojnik (2000). In particular, Zabojnik (2000) explores how hierarchical Þrms pay employees efficiency wages in accordance with the potential threat of their leaving the Þrm with relevant information.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…To see this, notice that in any SP Equilibrium and any subgame h ∈ H N , the sum of the continuation values of the informed agents cannot be larger than δ, i.e., P i∈K(h) v i (h) ≤ δ. 31 If the strategies are symmetric, the continuation values of all the informed players must be equal. Because the pie is bounded in size, this means that when there are many informed agents, the continuation value of each agent must converge to zero.…”
Section: Lemmamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In particular, as all firms in this equilibrium outsource, the structure of this equilibrium is independent on the parameter t. Thus, even in a market populated by contractors that are as efficient as in-house production (i.e., t = 0), one of them can emerge as the monopolist of the market for information. 36 To conclude the analysis of the equilibrium with a market for information, let us focus on the observable and derive some implications on the structure of this market. In the equilibrium described in Proposition 5, the market segments into four different sets of firms: the ones which invest in technology, the ones who buy 35 It is easy to show that if s ∈ [s, n), two cases are possible.…”
Section: Equilibrium Analysis 351 Equilibrium If S >mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…If t < e T , only no leakage equilibria, similar to the s = n case one, are possible. 36 Of course, this is because with the extremely simple information aggregation assumptions we have, every single firm does not have any impact on the knowledge of the monopolistic contractor. Still, even in a situation in which every firm's technology has a (decreasing) impact on the knowledge of the contractor, we could support a similar equilibrium for an arbitrarily low t.…”
Section: Equilibrium Analysis 351 Equilibrium If S >mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation