2000
DOI: 10.1016/s0167-6296(99)00028-4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Access to coverage for high-risks in a competitive individual health insurance market: via premium rate restrictions or risk-adjusted premium subsidies?

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

1
26
0
1

Year Published

2009
2009
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 63 publications
(28 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
1
26
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…They can provide subsidies to individuals-cash transfers, vouchers, tax-favored treatment, tax credits, etc.-to enable them to purchase high-cost insurance. Van de Ven and Schut (2011) note that premium subsidies are unlikely to be optimal for three reasons: they reduce the incentive for efficient purchasing of insurance by high-risk individuals; they encourage excess purchase of insurance and the resulting moral hazard effects (Zweifel and Manning 2000); and they may create a misallocation of subsides if the magnitude of the premium is based on elements that are not relevant for the level of the subsidy (such as differences in efficiency among health insurers or regional differences in prices). In contrast, risk-adjusted subsidies, where Where subsidies are provided by government to the insurer, individuals are then charged a community-rated contribution for insurance that is not based on their expected costs.…”
Section: Pooling Riskmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…They can provide subsidies to individuals-cash transfers, vouchers, tax-favored treatment, tax credits, etc.-to enable them to purchase high-cost insurance. Van de Ven and Schut (2011) note that premium subsidies are unlikely to be optimal for three reasons: they reduce the incentive for efficient purchasing of insurance by high-risk individuals; they encourage excess purchase of insurance and the resulting moral hazard effects (Zweifel and Manning 2000); and they may create a misallocation of subsides if the magnitude of the premium is based on elements that are not relevant for the level of the subsidy (such as differences in efficiency among health insurers or regional differences in prices). In contrast, risk-adjusted subsidies, where Where subsidies are provided by government to the insurer, individuals are then charged a community-rated contribution for insurance that is not based on their expected costs.…”
Section: Pooling Riskmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In contrast, risk-adjusted subsidies, where Where subsidies are provided by government to the insurer, individuals are then charged a community-rated contribution for insurance that is not based on their expected costs. Van de Ven and Schut (2011) refer to subsidies provided to insurers as risk equalization and note that these are far more common in practice than subsidies provided to individuals, due to lower transaction costs. The ultimate success of these risk adjustment mechanisms depends on ability to determine risk (van de Ven et al 2000).…”
Section: Pooling Riskmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Differently, if we include only ex post individual information in the payment formula, we reduce the risk assumed by health plans, and therefore the incentives for risk selection, although also the incentives for efficiency. When those models use ex post information on cost instead of other indicators of need, they belong to what has been called in the literature a risk sharing formula [30,31,35], while when they use ex post information on diagnosis, they present a concurrent risk adjustment scheme [34].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%