1991
DOI: 10.3905/jpm.1991.409309
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Asset allocation under shortfall constraints

Abstract: R ver the long term, equity investors have , -5 been richly rewarded for the risks that they have endured. For example, during the 1926-1987 period, the S&P provided an annual return advantage of 6.8%, compared with long-term corporate bonds. Over sh0rte.r periods, by contrast, stocks actually underperformed cash on a surprisingly frequent basis. In particular, stocks have underperformed Treasury bills over the past fifteen years in almost 35% of six-to eighteen-month time periods (see Salomon et al. [1990]).F… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
25
0

Year Published

2000
2000
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
5
3
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 63 publications
(25 citation statements)
references
References 2 publications
0
25
0
Order By: Relevance
“…. , n. The probabilistic requirement on the portfolio's return in (3) is called a shortfall constraint, see Leibowitz and Kogelman (1991) and Leibowitz et al (1992). As an alternative to (2) and (3), we could use a general utility function in order to characterize the manager's preferences.…”
Section: Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…. , n. The probabilistic requirement on the portfolio's return in (3) is called a shortfall constraint, see Leibowitz and Kogelman (1991) and Leibowitz et al (1992). As an alternative to (2) and (3), we could use a general utility function in order to characterize the manager's preferences.…”
Section: Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It was widely applied to investment asset allocation by Leibowitz et al (1996) and used by Leibowitz and Krasker (1988) and Maurer and Schlag (2003) among others to judge the long term risk of stocks and bonds. In addition Libby and Fishburn (1977); Kahneman and Tversky (1979);Laughhuun et al (1980) and March and Shapira (1987) show that in empirical business decisionmaking, many individuals judge the risk of an alternative relative to a reference point.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Different methodologies have been developed that move away from the standard mean-variance approach, by changing the risk measure of the portfolio. One branch of the literature considers portfolio selection with value at risk (Agarwal and Naik (2004), Martellini and Ziemann (2007)), or conditional VaR (Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000)); the other branch with shortfall probability (Leibowitz and Henriksson (1989), Leibowitz and Kogelman (1991), Lucas and Klaassen (1998), Billio and Casarin (2007), Smith and Gould (2007)). A useful development of our work would be to reconcile the two approaches and examine shortfall probabilities in the context of non-normal returns.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Roy defined the shortfall constraint such that the probability of the portfolio's value falling below a specified disaster level is limited to a specified disaster probability. Portfolio optimisations with a shortfall probability risk measure have been conducted before (Leibowitz and Henriksson (1989), Leibowitz and Kogelman (1991), Lucas and Klaassen (1998), Billio (2007), Smith and Gould (2007)), but as far as we know not in the context of an inflation hedging portfolio.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%