In this research we investigate the behavior of noise traders and their impact on the market. We do this in an experimental market setting that allows us to determine not only how noise traders fare in a competitive asset market with other traders, but also how the equilibrium changes if a securities transactions tax ("Tobin tax") is imposed. We find that noise traders lose money on average: they do not engage in extensive liquidity provision, and their attempt to make money by trend chasing is unsuccessful as they lose most in securities whose prices experience large moves. Noise traders adversely affect the informational efficiency of the market: they drive prices away from fundamental values, and the further away the market gets from the true value, the stronger this effect becomes. With a securities transaction tax, noise traders submit fewer orders and lose less money in those securities that exhibit large price movements. The tax is associated with a decrease in market trading volume, but informational efficiency remains essentially unchanged and liquidity (as measured by the price impact of trades) actually improves. We find no significant effect, however, on market volatility, suggesting that at least this rationale for a securities transaction tax is not supported by our data.
2
The Limits of Noise Trading: An Experimental AnalysisNoise traders play a ubiquitous role in the finance literature. Fischer Black [1986] dedicated his AFA presidential address to the beneficial effects of "noise" on markets, concluding that "noise trading is essential to the existence of liquid markets." Shleifer and and Shleifer and Vishny [1997] identified noise traders as the basis for the limits of arbitrage, arguing that noise trading introduces risks that inhibit arbitrageurs and prevent prices from converging to fundamental asset values. Noise traders in the guise of SOES bandits have been credited with enhancing price discovery (see Harris and Schultz [1998]), while their day trading counterparts have been disparaged for creating speculative bubbles in asset prices both home and abroad (Scheinkman and Xiong [2003]). The excessive volatility allegedly arising from noise trading is also blamed for a variety of economic ills ranging from market crashes to the failure of globalization.
1Despite this central importance, there remains considerable debate regarding the role of noise trading in financial markets. For example, there is little agreement as to whether noise trading enhances or detracts from informational efficiency; whether noise trading increases or decreases price volatility; or even whether noise traders can survive in financial markets, in either the short or the long run. This disagreement spills over into debates over whether society is well advised to limit noise trading by taxation or other means, or to ignore it altogether due to its inconsequential nature in affecting market outcomes.Undoubtedly, the confusion surrounding the role of noise traders stems in part from basic disagreements over ...