1995
DOI: 10.2307/2950427
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Asymmetric International Minimum Quality Standards and Vertical Differentiation

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3

Citation Types

2
73
2
4

Year Published

1999
1999
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 113 publications
(81 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
2
73
2
4
Order By: Relevance
“…Maxwell (1998), Puller (2006) and Garella (2006) evaluate the effects on the incentive to innovate; Boom (1995) and Lutz and Baliamoune-Lutz (2003) consider the role of minimum quality standards in international trade models; Lee and Phuyal (2013) In contrast to the more recent literature cited above we are not concerned with advanced topics like, e.g., collusion or the incentive to innovate. Instead, our work is in the spirit of the earlier contributions to the literature as we explore the more fundamental question whether or not a dynamic standard according to the Japanese Top Runner Program is an appropriate instrument at all when the regulator aims at increasing energy efficiency or total welfare.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Maxwell (1998), Puller (2006) and Garella (2006) evaluate the effects on the incentive to innovate; Boom (1995) and Lutz and Baliamoune-Lutz (2003) consider the role of minimum quality standards in international trade models; Lee and Phuyal (2013) In contrast to the more recent literature cited above we are not concerned with advanced topics like, e.g., collusion or the incentive to innovate. Instead, our work is in the spirit of the earlier contributions to the literature as we explore the more fundamental question whether or not a dynamic standard according to the Japanese Top Runner Program is an appropriate instrument at all when the regulator aims at increasing energy efficiency or total welfare.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We conjecture that the companies with certain characteristics such as international exposure for example obtain additional value from employing the same financial reporting system as the rest of the network participants will continue to rise. To this end, these firms drive the standardization process by adopting the same set of standards rather early [11][12][13][14][15][16]. To this purpose, instead of examining gains and losses associated with IFRS adoption, we identify firm-specific characteristics that associate with the likelihood of the adoption.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In addition, in a period of globalization it is important to better understand firm-specific characteristics associated with companies' decisions to standardize their business practices, and financial reporting in particular [7][8][9][10][11][12][13][14][15][16][17][18][19][20][21][22][23][24][25]. For the purpose of our study, our sample of companies have been grouped into three categories (1) early adopters, (2) those that presumably lack the incentives to adopt early 2005 adopters; and (3) those that did not perceive IFRS adoption advantages, and thus postponed the adoption (2007 adopters).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Crampes and Hollander (1995) investigated the use of a MQS with quality-dependent marginal costs and found that in contrast to Ronnen (1991) a MQS may not always benet consumers. Boom (1995) added the international trade dimension and showed how asymmetric quality regulation in dierent countries could have spillover eects in otherwise segregated markets.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%