2017
DOI: 10.1111/1756-2171.12189
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Auctions versus negotiations: the effects of inefficient renegotiation

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

0
13
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 19 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 33 publications
0
13
0
Order By: Relevance
“…A behavioral foundation based on loss aversion for inefficient renegotiation is developed by Herweg and Schmidt (2015). Other contributions like Bajari and Tadelis (2001) and Herweg and Schmidt (2017) start out from the assumption that renegotiation is costly and investigate the implications. Bajari and Tadelis (2001) compare fixed-price to cost-plus contracts and show that standardized goods should be procured by fixed-price contracts that give strong cost-saving incentives to sellers, while complex goods should be procured by cost-plus contracts in order to avoid costly renegotiation.…”
Section: Relation To the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…A behavioral foundation based on loss aversion for inefficient renegotiation is developed by Herweg and Schmidt (2015). Other contributions like Bajari and Tadelis (2001) and Herweg and Schmidt (2017) start out from the assumption that renegotiation is costly and investigate the implications. Bajari and Tadelis (2001) compare fixed-price to cost-plus contracts and show that standardized goods should be procured by fixed-price contracts that give strong cost-saving incentives to sellers, while complex goods should be procured by cost-plus contracts in order to avoid costly renegotiation.…”
Section: Relation To the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Bajari and Tadelis (2001) compare fixed-price to cost-plus contracts and show that standardized goods should be procured by fixed-price contracts that give strong cost-saving incentives to sellers, while complex goods should be procured by cost-plus contracts in order to avoid costly renegotiation. Herweg and Schmidt (2017) compare price-only auctions to bilateral negotiations. They show that negotiation with one selected seller may outperform an auction because the auction induces sellers to conceal private information about design improvements which gives rise to inefficient renegotiation.…”
Section: Relation To the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…A classic strand of the literature investigates moral hazard as the main source of renegotiation (Fudenberg and Tirole, 1990 or Herweg and Schmidt, 2015 for a more recent contribution). Another line of reasoning identifies design flaws as a source of renegotiation (Herweg and Schmidt, 2017;Herweg and Schwarz, 2018). Suppliers have private information about potential design flaws of the procurement project and leverage this information to capture additional rents during the project.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Finally, costly renegotiation of incomplete procurement contracts is analyzed by Bajari and Tadelis (2001) and Herweg and Schmidt (2017). The former paper analyzes when fixed-price contracts outperform cost-plus contracts, whereas the latter one derives conditions so that bilateral negotiations outperform procurement auctions.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…If the procurer can specify a maximum bid R-that is, only price bids p ≤ R are allowed in the second-price auction-and this maximum bid is publicly announced before suppliers place their bids, it is still optimal for the procurer to specify x = x L initially(Herweg and Schwarz, 2016).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%