2015
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2657057
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Bubble Formation and (In)Efficient Markets in Learning-to-Forecast and -Optimise Experiments

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

6
113
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 39 publications
(119 citation statements)
references
References 47 publications
6
113
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The literature provides numerous contributions in this field, using both negative (Hommes et al (2007), Bao et al (2012)) and positive (Hommes et al (2005), Bottazzi et al (2011), Anufriev and Hommes (2012)) feedback system. Moreover, a more recent strand of literature propose the so-called "Learning to Optimize" (Bao et al (2013), Bao et al (2014)) in which subjects make the best choice in terms of productions (for a comparison of these methods see Duffy (2010)). Evidence from these experiments suggests that, in general, there is strong coordination in the group and that there is convergence to the rational equilibrium only if we consider negative feedback.…”
Section: Description Of the Experimentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The literature provides numerous contributions in this field, using both negative (Hommes et al (2007), Bao et al (2012)) and positive (Hommes et al (2005), Bottazzi et al (2011), Anufriev and Hommes (2012)) feedback system. Moreover, a more recent strand of literature propose the so-called "Learning to Optimize" (Bao et al (2013), Bao et al (2014)) in which subjects make the best choice in terms of productions (for a comparison of these methods see Duffy (2010)). Evidence from these experiments suggests that, in general, there is strong coordination in the group and that there is convergence to the rational equilibrium only if we consider negative feedback.…”
Section: Description Of the Experimentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The lower their forecast error, the higher their payo. We use the quadratic payo function, as in Bao et al (2016) :…”
Section: The Learning-to-forecast Experiments (Ltfe)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In the second design a so-called Learning-to-Optimize experiment (LtOE), see e.g. Bao et al (2013Bao et al ( , 2016, we drop the assumption of optimal conditional savings decisions, and ask the subjects to directly submit the savings quantity of a young individual. This savings decision may be based on his forecast of the return on savings P t /P e t+1 , but we do not explicitly elicit return forecasts from subjects.…”
Section: The Learning-to-optimize Experiments (Ltoe)mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…It then becomes natural to measure the performance of subjects in terms of gains, utility or profits and reward them accordingly. Recently some learning-to-forecast and learning-to-optimize experiments have been run by Bao et al (2013Bao et al ( , 2014, where both tasks had to be performed and the rewards are profits and/or utility. This extends the results of chapter 8 and it appears that convergence in negative feedback experiments becomes slower, while bubbles in positive feedback experiments become more severe.…”
Section: Cars Hommesmentioning
confidence: 99%