2021
DOI: 10.1111/caje.12527
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Can public spending boost private consumption?

Abstract: One of the most debated issues in modern macroeconomics relates to the behaviour of private consumption in response to an increase in government spending. Recent empirical studies have found a positive relationship between these two macroeconomic fundamentals. However, such a finding cannot be easily reconciled with simple real business cycle models. In this paper, we develop and estimate a new Keynesian model that is able to predict a rise in consumption in response to an increase in productive public spendin… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2022
2022
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
4

Relationship

0
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 4 publications
(3 citation statements)
references
References 90 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…As a consequence, when maximising utility, households take into account the level of public consumption, because this type of government spending is partly a substitute for private consumption (Asimakopoulos et al, 2021). Conversely, public investment is not included in the household utility function, because it is not a substitute for private consumption.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…As a consequence, when maximising utility, households take into account the level of public consumption, because this type of government spending is partly a substitute for private consumption (Asimakopoulos et al, 2021). Conversely, public investment is not included in the household utility function, because it is not a substitute for private consumption.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Firstly, public investment affects public capital, and as a consequence increases the productive capacity of the economy, whereas public consumption does not affect the production function (Baxter and King, 1993;Kamps, 2004;Bom and Ligthart, 2014;Dinlersoz and Fu, 2020). Secondly, public investment, unlike public consumption, is not a substitute for private consumption, which leads to weaker crowding-out of private consumption (Karras, 1994;Kwan, 2006;Ercolani and Azevedo, 2014;Ambler et al, 2017;Asimakopoulos et al, 2021).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2 In contrast, Linnemann (2006) considers non-separable utility function between consumption and leisure and shows that the consumption multiplier can be positive when consumption and government spending are substitutes in a frictionless business cycle model for a certain functional form of preferences. However, Bilbiie (2009) shows that, for general utility function, the parameter restriction under which a positive consumption multiplier occurs in a frictionless business cycle model implies that either the utility function is not concave or that 1 These modifications include productive government spending (Baxter and King (1993); Asimakopoulos, Lorusso, and Pieroni (2021)), hand-to-mouth households (Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2007)), deep habit (Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Urbe (2006)), and others.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%