2001
DOI: 10.1016/s0304-3932(01)00052-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Common cycles and the importance of transitory shocks to macroeconomic aggregates

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

1
70
0
5

Year Published

2007
2007
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
1
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 76 publications
(76 citation statements)
references
References 25 publications
1
70
0
5
Order By: Relevance
“…5 Other applications of common cycles and common trends methodology in business cycles (national, local and sectoral), macroeconomic variables, health expenditures, metals and commodities can be found in the papers, such as: Vahid and Engle (1993), Engle and Issler (1995), Issler and Vahid (2001), Narayan (2008), Narayan and Narayan (2008a, b), and Issler et al, (2014). 6 Common trends and cycles can also be introduced into the multivariate structural time series model of Harvey (1989) and Koopman et al (2000).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…5 Other applications of common cycles and common trends methodology in business cycles (national, local and sectoral), macroeconomic variables, health expenditures, metals and commodities can be found in the papers, such as: Vahid and Engle (1993), Engle and Issler (1995), Issler and Vahid (2001), Narayan (2008), Narayan and Narayan (2008a, b), and Issler et al, (2014). 6 Common trends and cycles can also be introduced into the multivariate structural time series model of Harvey (1989) and Koopman et al (2000).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While, cointegration is a common feature, another common feature of interest is the presence of common serial correlation patterns, i.e., common cycles. Issler and Vahid (2001) pointed out that the joint modeling of common-trend and commoncycle restrictions to identify permanent and transitory shocks has a clear advantage over the use of common-trend restrictions only. Understandably, if common-cycle restrictions are correctly imposed, estimates of the dynamic model (traditionally, a vector autoregression (VAR) model) are more precise, and leads to more accurate measurement of the relative importance of permanent and transitory shocks.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Indeed, common cycles appear in many theoretical economic models. For examples, in models of aggregate consumption behavior as discussed in Vahid and Engle (1993) and Issler and Vahid (2001), the proportion of total income that accrues to "myopic" individuals (Campbell and Mankiw, 1990), that is, individuals that consume their income entirely in every period, or excess sensitivity of consumption to current income (Flavin, 1993), provide that first differences of I(1) consumption and income share a common cycle. Note that in the consumption theory of Hall (1978) consumption and income share only a common stochastic trend.…”
Section: Common Cyclesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The common stochastic trend is generated by an integrated productivity shock, while the deviation of capital stock from its steady state value determines the transitional dynamics of output, consumption and investment. Other example is Campbell (1987) where the saving path implies that disposable income and consumption cointegrate (Issler and Vahid, 2001). However, it could happen that observed comovements are in contrast with the theoretical model, and some efforts are toward reconciling the model with the data: as an example, in the DSGE model of Justiniano et al (2010), an extension of the well known model of Christiano et al (2005), investment shocks are the driven forces of fluctuations over the business cycle.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%