1988
DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1988.tb04593.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Compensation and Incentives: Practice vs. Theory

Abstract: A thorough understanding of internal incentive structures is critical to developing a viable theory of the firm, since these incentives determine to a large extent how individuals inside an organization behave. Many common features of organizational incentive systems are not easily explained by traditional economic theory-including egalitarian pay systems in which compensation is largely independent of performance, the overwhelming use of promotion-based incentive systems, the absence of up-front fees for jobs… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

24
578
1
44

Year Published

1997
1997
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
9
1

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 1,384 publications
(647 citation statements)
references
References 28 publications
24
578
1
44
Order By: Relevance
“…We include several measures of lagged firm performance, namely stock return, return on assets (ROA) and sales growth in year t − 1, since better performing managers will be better remunerated. We also control for the lagged firm sales, which has been used as a measure for firm size and complexity (e.g., Baker, Jensen, & Murphy (1988)), and for the lagged market value, which is a proxy for the present value of the firm's growth opportunities, since all these firm characteristics have been shown to influence CEO compensation (e.g., Murphy (1999)). 15 We control for the Bebchuk, Cohen, & Ferrell (2009) entrenchment index since powerful CEOs may extract more pay, as well as for the firm's stock volatility as it can mechanically drive the value of compensation, particularly the value of option grants.…”
Section: Annual Data Results and Robustness Checksmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We include several measures of lagged firm performance, namely stock return, return on assets (ROA) and sales growth in year t − 1, since better performing managers will be better remunerated. We also control for the lagged firm sales, which has been used as a measure for firm size and complexity (e.g., Baker, Jensen, & Murphy (1988)), and for the lagged market value, which is a proxy for the present value of the firm's growth opportunities, since all these firm characteristics have been shown to influence CEO compensation (e.g., Murphy (1999)). 15 We control for the Bebchuk, Cohen, & Ferrell (2009) entrenchment index since powerful CEOs may extract more pay, as well as for the firm's stock volatility as it can mechanically drive the value of compensation, particularly the value of option grants.…”
Section: Annual Data Results and Robustness Checksmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Empirically, a large number of studies have shown that bonuses are positively correlated with employees' performance (Groves et al, 1994;Baker et al, 1988;Banker et al, 2000;Enis, 1993;Jones and Kato, 1995;Kahn and Sherer, 1990). Furthermore, beyond providing monetary incentives, experiments also show that a bonus can also trigger gift-exchange considerations and induce some agents to expend more effort than under an incentive contract (Fehr et al (2007)).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…These include the internal governance structures such as smaller boards (Yermack, 1996), a higher degree of board independence (Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990) and CEO ownership (McConnell and Servaes, 1990). As a major explanation for CEO pay (e.g., Baker et al, 1988;Jensen and Murphy, 1990), agency theory has been challenged by the corporate compensation practices (Mintzberg, 2009) and it has also been criticize for its inability of cross-country difference (Haubrich and Popova, 1998; Bruce et al, 2005; Filatotchev and Allcock, 2010).…”
Section: "The Directors Of Such Companies However Being the Managermentioning
confidence: 99%