2018
DOI: 10.1111/1756-2171.12225
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Consumer obfuscation by a multiproduct firm

Abstract: also analyzes obfuscation and the price choices of a multiproduct monopolist with horizontally differentiated products. Unlike the present article, he places fewer restrictions on the distributions of match values and focuses on markets with more than two products and observable prices. For these reasons, some of his results and welfare findings differ from the present article, including showing that obfuscation might improve welfare.By obfuscating some of its products, the monopolist controls the order in whi… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 38 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 45 publications
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Our customer utility and search model within this framework follows recent work in the search literature that examines obfuscation in settings with monopolistic competition (e.g., Armstrong 2017; Gamp 2019; Petrikaitė 2018). We consider a representative consumer who earns utility u j from buying product j, which equals the difference between her match value ϵ j and the price p j of the product, given price sensitivity α [ 0 , 1 ] : u j = ϵ j αp j .…”
Section: Theoretical Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our customer utility and search model within this framework follows recent work in the search literature that examines obfuscation in settings with monopolistic competition (e.g., Armstrong 2017; Gamp 2019; Petrikaitė 2018). We consider a representative consumer who earns utility u j from buying product j, which equals the difference between her match value ϵ j and the price p j of the product, given price sensitivity α [ 0 , 1 ] : u j = ϵ j αp j .…”
Section: Theoretical Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The remaining proportion of consumers have a common search cost . The Bertrand(1883) [8] result and the Diamond(1971) [9] result obtain in the model when, and , respectively. When , there is no pure-strategy Nash Equilibrium(NE), but there is a unique symmetric NE in mixed strategies.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 87%
“…Our research also connects to the broader consumer search literature (see, e.g., Anderson and Renault 1999;Diamond 1971;Dukes and Zhu 2019;Janssen, Moraga-Gonzalez, and Wildenbeest 2005;Janssen and Shelegia 2015;Jiang, Kumar, and Ratchford 2017;Ke and Lin 2020;Kuksov 2004;Lal and Sarvary 1999;McCall 1970;Stahl 1989;Stigler 1961;Weitzman 1979;Wolinsky 1986;Zhong 2020;Zhu and Dukes 2017;Zou and Jiang 2020). Within this large and diverse literature, our work is most closely informed by the ordered-search stream (e.g., Arbatskaya 2007;Armstrong, Vickers, and Zhou 2009;Armstrong and Zhou 2011;Astorne-Figaria and Yankelevich 2014;Cao and Zhu 2020;Choi, Dai, and Kim 2018;Janssen and Ke 2020;Mamadehussene 2019;Petrikaitė2018;Wilson 2010;Xu, Chen, and Whinston 2011). Here, instead of randomly sampling from the available options, customers search in a deliberate sequence, visiting certain firms early in the sequence, thus advantaging those firms.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%