1997
DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb02754.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Cost of Transacting and Expected Returns in the Nasdaq Market

Abstract: This article empirically examines the liquidity premium predicted by the Amihud and Mendelson (1986) model using Nasdaq data over the 1973–1990 period. The results support the model and are much stronger than for the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), as reported by Chen and Kan (1989) and Eleswarapu and Reinganum (1993). I conjecture that the stronger evidence on the Nasdaq is due to the dealers' inside spreads on the Nasdaq being a better proxy for the actual cost of transacting than the quoted spreads on the N… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

6
53
0

Year Published

2005
2005
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
5
4
1

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 144 publications
(59 citation statements)
references
References 19 publications
6
53
0
Order By: Relevance
“…1 Consequently, the estimated effect of the bidask spread is expected to be stronger when using Nasdaq stocks. This is indeed the finding by Eleswarapu (1997), who estimates a model where the stock return is regressed on the stock's beta, relative spread, and log(size). The estimation is performed for individual stocks employing the Fama and MacBeth (1973) method.…”
Section: Cross-section Testsmentioning
confidence: 88%
“…1 Consequently, the estimated effect of the bidask spread is expected to be stronger when using Nasdaq stocks. This is indeed the finding by Eleswarapu (1997), who estimates a model where the stock return is regressed on the stock's beta, relative spread, and log(size). The estimation is performed for individual stocks employing the Fama and MacBeth (1973) method.…”
Section: Cross-section Testsmentioning
confidence: 88%
“…In a seminal paper, Amihud and Mendelson (1986) develop a model and empirical tests to demonstrate that asset returns are positively related to their proxy for illiquidity, that is, the relative bid-ask spread. Other evidence supports and explores these findings (e.g., see Amihud and Mendelson, 1989;Eleswarapu, 1997;Jacoby et al 2000;Gottesman and Jacoby, 2006).…”
mentioning
confidence: 71%
“…By and large, the empirical literature based on modern data supports this view. For example, Asparouhova et al (2010), Eleswarapu (1997) and Chalmers and Kadlec (1998) support the hypothesis of a positive risk premium for illiquidity; Baltagi et al (2006) and Hau (2006) illustrate that higher transaction costs come along with higher volatility.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 97%