2006
DOI: 10.1007/s11166-006-8289-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Cumulative prospect theory's functional menagerie

Abstract: Many different functional forms have been suggested for both the value function and probability weighting function of Cumulative Prospect Theory (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992). There are also many stochastic choice functions available. Since these three components only make predictions when considered in combination, this paper examines the complete pattern of 256 model variants that can be constructed from twenty functions. All these variants are fit to experimental data and their explanatory power assessed. Si… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

32
373
3
3

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
3

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 429 publications
(411 citation statements)
references
References 81 publications
32
373
3
3
Order By: Relevance
“…For losses, however, the reliabilities were similar for the second and third iteration. These reliabilities are comparable to those of earlier studies (Abdellaoui et al, 2008;Stott, 2006).…”
Section: Reliabilitysupporting
confidence: 89%
“…For losses, however, the reliabilities were similar for the second and third iteration. These reliabilities are comparable to those of earlier studies (Abdellaoui et al, 2008;Stott, 2006).…”
Section: Reliabilitysupporting
confidence: 89%
“…which can be conveniently interpreted and has turned out to be the best compromise between parsimony and goodness of fit in the context of prospect theory (Stott, 2006). 6…”
Section: Econometric Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Several parametric functions have been proposed to describe the probably weighting function (see Stott 2006 for an overview). The most commonly used specification is the linear-in-log-odds specification, introduced by Goldstein and Einhorn (1987) (GE-87), and given by:…”
Section: Parametric Specificationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The correlation then becomes: corr ε o+ 1,n , ε o+ 2,n = cov ε o+ 1,n , ε o+ 2,n var ε o+ 1,n · var ε o+ 2,n = −σ 2 2σ 2 · 2σ 2 = − 1 2 . 7 In the context of discrete choice, Stott (2006) shows that the more parsimonious one-parameter specifications often provide a sufficient fit in terms of the Akaike information criterion. …”
Section: The Econometric Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%