2002
DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00490
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Differences of Opinion and the Cross Section of Stock Returns

Abstract: We provide evidence that stocks with higher dispersion in analysts' earnings forecasts earn lower future returns than otherwise similar stocks. This effect is most pronounced in small stocks and stocks that have performed poorly over the past year. Interpreting dispersion in analysts' forecasts as a proxy for differences in opinion about a stock, we show that this evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that prices will ref lect the optimistic view whenever investors with the lowest valuations do not trade.… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

102
1,159
22
5

Year Published

2005
2005
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 1,845 publications
(1,288 citation statements)
references
References 47 publications
102
1,159
22
5
Order By: Relevance
“…Anderson, Ghysels, and Juergens (2005) took the disagreement of forecasters about the future values of variables as an 2 indication of heterogeneity in the beliefs of agents and showed how the disagreement is priced in a heterogeneous agents model with micro-foundations. Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) rationalize their findings that higher dispersion stocks have lower future returns with arguments from the short-sale constraints literature, in particular Miller (1977). They argue dispersion proxies for differences of opinions among traders where only the most optimistic opinions are reflected, thereby driving up current prices.…”
supporting
confidence: 57%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Anderson, Ghysels, and Juergens (2005) took the disagreement of forecasters about the future values of variables as an 2 indication of heterogeneity in the beliefs of agents and showed how the disagreement is priced in a heterogeneous agents model with micro-foundations. Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) rationalize their findings that higher dispersion stocks have lower future returns with arguments from the short-sale constraints literature, in particular Miller (1977). They argue dispersion proxies for differences of opinions among traders where only the most optimistic opinions are reflected, thereby driving up current prices.…”
supporting
confidence: 57%
“…They argue dispersion proxies for differences of opinions among traders where only the most optimistic opinions are reflected, thereby driving up current prices. Johnson (2004) offers an alternative explanation to the findings of Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002). In his model, levered firms may be able to reduce the cost of capital by increasing idiosyncratic risk of earnings volatility and subsequently the dispersion of earnings forecasts.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…See Brennan and Subrahmanyam (1995); Aboody and Lev (2000); and Wu (2004). Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) show that the dispersion of the earnings forecasts by analysts is a measure of asymmetric information. We also find that companies issuing structured PIPEs have a significantly higher dispersion of earnings forecasts than companies issuing traditional PIPEs.…”
Section: Characteristics Of Pipe Companiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…More recently, several authors have relied on proxies for short-sale constraints or demand (Chen, Hong, and Stein (2002) -breadth of ownership, Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002), Nagel (2004) -institutional ownership, Lamont (2004) -firm's actions to impede short-selling), and even the actual cost of borrowing stock (D'Avolio (2002), Cohen, Diether, and Malloy (2005),…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%