2021
DOI: 10.1002/fut.22188
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Disproportionate costs of uncertainty: Small bank hedging and Dodd‐Frank

Abstract: Uncertainty in banking regulation may impose widespread economic costs by increasing financial constraints on credit availability. Four years of Dodd‐Frank uncertainty over undecided risk weightings increased regulatory uncertainty for smaller banks, restricting “vanilla” interest rate hedging activities. This paper uses newly reported mortgage banking data as an identification strategy and finds that when costs of uncertainty are removed, small banks hedge 97%–120% more interest rate risk while mortgage secur… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
11
0

Year Published

2021
2021
2025
2025

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

1
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(12 citation statements)
references
References 46 publications
1
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Using this approach, I obtain similar overall findings as Table 4, confirming this paper's findings are not driven by sample selection bias. The first stage in Equation (2) is a Probit model where the independent variables are motivated by Bliss et al (2018), Kim (2021), Purnanandam (2007), and Sinkey and Carter (2000) specified as center center left0.33emtruePr(Hedgeri,t=1)=ϕα+γ1log(Assets)+γ2Loansi,tAssetsi,t+γ3NPAi,tAssetsi,t+γ4Depositsi,tAssetsi,t+γ4MathClass-open[italicHTMitalic italicLosses, italicAFSitalic italicLosses, italicMaturityitalic italicGapMathClass-close]i,tAssetsi,t+εi,t. $\begin{array}{ccc}Pr({{Hedger}}_{i,t}=1) & = & \phi \left[\alpha +{\gamma }_{1}log(Assets)+{\gamma }_{2}\frac{Loan{s}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\gamma }_{3}\frac{NP{A}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\gamma }_{4}\frac{Deposit{s}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}\right.\\ & & \left.+{\gamma }_{4}\frac{{[{HTM}{\unicode{x02007}}{Losses},\unicode{x02007}{AFS}{\unicode{x02007}}{Losses},\unicode{x02007}{Maturity}{\unicode{x02007}}{Gap}]}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\varepsilon }_{i,t}\right].\end{array}$…”
Section: Empirical Model and Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 4 more Smart Citations
“…Using this approach, I obtain similar overall findings as Table 4, confirming this paper's findings are not driven by sample selection bias. The first stage in Equation (2) is a Probit model where the independent variables are motivated by Bliss et al (2018), Kim (2021), Purnanandam (2007), and Sinkey and Carter (2000) specified as center center left0.33emtruePr(Hedgeri,t=1)=ϕα+γ1log(Assets)+γ2Loansi,tAssetsi,t+γ3NPAi,tAssetsi,t+γ4Depositsi,tAssetsi,t+γ4MathClass-open[italicHTMitalic italicLosses, italicAFSitalic italicLosses, italicMaturityitalic italicGapMathClass-close]i,tAssetsi,t+εi,t. $\begin{array}{ccc}Pr({{Hedger}}_{i,t}=1) & = & \phi \left[\alpha +{\gamma }_{1}log(Assets)+{\gamma }_{2}\frac{Loan{s}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\gamma }_{3}\frac{NP{A}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\gamma }_{4}\frac{Deposit{s}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}\right.\\ & & \left.+{\gamma }_{4}\frac{{[{HTM}{\unicode{x02007}}{Losses},\unicode{x02007}{AFS}{\unicode{x02007}}{Losses},\unicode{x02007}{Maturity}{\unicode{x02007}}{Gap}]}_{i,t}}{Asset{s}_{i,t}}+{\varepsilon }_{i,t}\right].\end{array}$…”
Section: Empirical Model and Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This raises concerns that the panel data in Table 4 is subject to selection bias when hedging IRD is the dependent variable. Similar to Bliss et al (2018), Kim (2021), and Purnanandam (2007), I deploy a Heckman (1979) two‐stage model that uses maximum likelihood estimation to correct for any sample selection bias. Using this approach, I obtain similar overall findings as Table 4, confirming this paper's findings are not driven by sample selection bias.…”
Section: Empirical Model and Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations