Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Terms of use:
Documents in
www.econstor.euThe paper has benefited from comments and suggestions from George Borjas, J. David Brown, Curtis Florence, Jerry Gonzalez, Gordon Hanson, Robert E. Moore, Pia Orrenius, Giovanni Peri, Debra Sabia, Eric Seiber, Chad Sparber, Madeline Zavodny, and seminar participants at the Departments of Economics at the Georgia Institute of Technology, the University of Kentucky, the University of Georgia Department of Public Administration and Policy, Claremont-McKenna College, and the University of California-Riverside. The research assistance of Gustavo Canavire, M. Laurel Graefe, Gustavo Uceda, and Eric Wang is much appreciated. The views expressed here are the authors' and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System. Any remaining errors are the authors' responsibility. Abstract: Using administrative, individual-level, longitudinal data from the state of Georgia, this paper finds that a documented worker employed by a firm that hires undocumented workers can expect to earn 0.15 percent less than if employed by a firm that does not hire undocumented workers. However, in sectors where there are opportunities for task specialization and benefits from communication skills, documented workers can expect to earn a wage premium of less than 1 percent from being employed at a firm that also hires undocumented workers.JEL classification: J30, J15