2021
DOI: 10.1177/09589287211018146
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Do social investment policies reduce income inequality? An analysis of industrial countries

Abstract: Scholars and policymakers who call for social investment (SI) policies hope that SI policies reduce income inequality and poverty, among other policy goals. Meanwhile, some others point out potentially less pro-poor effects of SI policies. There are relatively few cross-national studies that empirically examine the distributional effects of SI policies. The current study seeks to fill the gap by investigating the effects of SI policies on income inequality in OECD countries. The empirical analysis finds mixed … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

1
6
0

Year Published

2022
2022
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

1
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 8 publications
(7 citation statements)
references
References 34 publications
1
6
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In the sense of the significant links between LMPs and disposable income inequalities, our results are in line with the majority of previous studies (Checchi and Garcia-Peñalosa 2008;2010;Sakamoto 2021). However, given the adopted method, we were not able to distinguish between the active and passive LMPs' relationships with income inequalities or to confirm if active (Sakamoto 2021) or passive LMPs (Burniaux, Padrini, and Brandt 2006;Checchi and Garcia-Peñalosa 2008) play a more important role in tackling income inequalities to achieve social cohesion.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 93%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…In the sense of the significant links between LMPs and disposable income inequalities, our results are in line with the majority of previous studies (Checchi and Garcia-Peñalosa 2008;2010;Sakamoto 2021). However, given the adopted method, we were not able to distinguish between the active and passive LMPs' relationships with income inequalities or to confirm if active (Sakamoto 2021) or passive LMPs (Burniaux, Padrini, and Brandt 2006;Checchi and Garcia-Peñalosa 2008) play a more important role in tackling income inequalities to achieve social cohesion.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 93%
“…Most often, disposable income inequalities are considered when their links to LMPs are considered (Checchi and Garcia-Peñalosa 2008;OECD 2012). Although some active LMPs may be associated with concepts related to labour income or market income inequalities, such as motivating individuals to develop their personal qualifications and education for higher future earnings (European Commission 2017a; Romero and Kuddo 2019), there is no evidence that active LMPs reduce market income inequalities (Sakamoto 2021). We considered different income inequality measures, such as market income, disposable income, and labour income, which sustains the novelty of the analysis.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Considering that workers in non-essential sectors already have lower wages and low-skilled workers usually have fewer opportunities both to work from home (Adams-Prassl et al, 2020; Bonacini et al, 2021) and to move across productive sectors (because of their lower endowment of general human capital), the risk of an increase in market and disposable income inequality once the pandemic emergency will end might become markedly concrete. Therefore, this risk might become more serious if effective structural predistributive policies (that is, social investment and active labour market policies and measures affecting labour market equilibria) and redistributive policies are not implemented and combined (Bozio et al, 2020; Sakamoto, 2021).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Furthermore, changes in the size of the target group affect spending levels independent of the benefit level. Instead, we relate family policy expenses to the target group (measuring spending levels per child) (Sakamoto, 2021). We divide childcare expenses by the number of children below the common school entry age of 6 years, and family allowances by the number of children and young people below 20 years.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%