2006
DOI: 10.1007/s11127-006-9017-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Does the Fed Contribute to a Political Business Cycle?

Abstract: In contrast to findings of other studies, evidence is presented to support the existence of a Federal Reserve-induced political monetary cycle that corresponds to the U.S. presidential election cycle. Using various Taylor rules, we find support for the view that Fed policy turns significantly more expansionary in the seven quarters prior to the election, but only when the Fed chair and incumbent presidential party have partisan affiliations. Copyright Springer Science+Business Media, Inc. 2006

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
51
0
1

Year Published

2007
2007
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 58 publications
(54 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
(23 reference statements)
2
51
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Moreover, the idea of an "electoral business cycle" has an honorable academic history, implicating the use of Keynesian tools, especially fiscal policy, to stimulate the economy in advance of an election (Nordhaus 1974;Tufte 1978;Alesina and Sachs 1988). The idea that the Federal Reserve might engage in such behavior systematically 10 is more controversial; although it has found support in one recent paper with an approach similar to ours (Abrams and Iossifov 2006), 11 the consensus view remains adverse. Drazen (2000) provides a survey, finding no evidence of electoral cycles in real activity, inflation, money growth, or the federal funds rate.…”
Section: Federal Reserve Policy and Presidential Electionsmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…Moreover, the idea of an "electoral business cycle" has an honorable academic history, implicating the use of Keynesian tools, especially fiscal policy, to stimulate the economy in advance of an election (Nordhaus 1974;Tufte 1978;Alesina and Sachs 1988). The idea that the Federal Reserve might engage in such behavior systematically 10 is more controversial; although it has found support in one recent paper with an approach similar to ours (Abrams and Iossifov 2006), 11 the consensus view remains adverse. Drazen (2000) provides a survey, finding no evidence of electoral cycles in real activity, inflation, money growth, or the federal funds rate.…”
Section: Federal Reserve Policy and Presidential Electionsmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…Gamber and Hakes (1997), Abrams and Iossifov (2006) and Galbraith et al (2007) investigated this issue with respect to the US Federal Reserve. All studies can only identify a political business cycle when additionally the party in charge (democratic or republican) is taken into account.…”
Section: Political Business Cycles and Monetary Policymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Since the decision to tighten credit or allow inflation has a redistributive consequence for borrowers and lenders, politicians may "outsource" decisions such as these to agencies believed not to be accountable to them, to "pass the buck" in terms of perceived responsibility for politically unpopular choices. Third, given the secrecy of central bank actions and the absence of a need to provide public reasons for their actions, politicians may well believe that they can influence central bank decisions in ways that escape public scrutiny, with central bank authorities sensitive to the desires of their politicians who appointed them (Abrams and Iossifov, 2006;Abrams, 2006;.…”
Section: Put Itmentioning
confidence: 99%