2017
DOI: 10.1093/jjfinec/nbx020
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Downside Variance Risk Premium*

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

4
47
1

Year Published

2017
2017
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 106 publications
(52 citation statements)
references
References 49 publications
4
47
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Thus, the joint estimation results for the GSARV and CGSARV specifications are consistent with the intuition that investors dislike downside uncertainty and demand a positive premium as compensation for bearing that risk, whereas they find upside uncertainty desirable and are willing to pay (negative premium) for exposure to such risk. A typical investor's asymmetric behavior toward good versus bad uncertainty is in line with the empirical regularities documented in recent works, such as those by Feunou et al (2018) and Feunou, Jahan-Parvar, and Tédongap (2013), among others. Moreover, the joint estimation results for the GSARV and CGSARV (ω ≡ ω u = ω d ) models are close, which suggests that the wedge between upside and downside conditional volatilities (h u,t − h d,t ) is the main driver of the conditional skewness in our option valuation framework.…”
Section: Model Fitsupporting
confidence: 86%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Thus, the joint estimation results for the GSARV and CGSARV specifications are consistent with the intuition that investors dislike downside uncertainty and demand a positive premium as compensation for bearing that risk, whereas they find upside uncertainty desirable and are willing to pay (negative premium) for exposure to such risk. A typical investor's asymmetric behavior toward good versus bad uncertainty is in line with the empirical regularities documented in recent works, such as those by Feunou et al (2018) and Feunou, Jahan-Parvar, and Tédongap (2013), among others. Moreover, the joint estimation results for the GSARV and CGSARV (ω ≡ ω u = ω d ) models are close, which suggests that the wedge between upside and downside conditional volatilities (h u,t − h d,t ) is the main driver of the conditional skewness in our option valuation framework.…”
Section: Model Fitsupporting
confidence: 86%
“…This decomposition of the realized variance into its up and down components is used by Patton and Sheppard (2015) to assess the information content and the predictive ability of signed squared jumps. In a recent study, Feunou, Jahan-Parvar, and Okou (2018) investigate the asymmetric behavior of investors towards good versus bad uncertainty by analyzing the premia related to upside and downside realized variances. Moreover, the difference between realized upside and downside variance, also known as the signed jump variation, can be perceived as a measure of (realized) skewness.…”
Section: A Separating Downside From Upside Volatility: Theoretical Amentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Their liquidity unconstrained counterparts, by contrast, cut prices during this period, a move consistent with the standard pricing models and the New Keynesian paradigm. 4 To rationalize the fact that firms' balance sheet positions influenced their pricing behavior during the financial crisis, we incorporate the theoretical insights of Chevalier and Scharfstein (1996) into a tractable general equilibrium model, in which monopolistically competitive firms face costly price adjustment, while setting prices to actively manage current versus future expected demand. We do so in the context of the deep habits framework formulated by Ravn, Schmitt-Grohe, and Uribe (2006), which we augment with a financial distortion, namely, costly external equity finance.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We follow Andersen & Bondarenko (2010), Andersen et al (2015) and Feunou et al (2015) and decompose the total variance risk premium into the downside and upside components. The results show that the upside and downside variance risk premium also pass both tests by providing evidence for significantly predicting excess returns and variance in-sample, and in adding economic value in a timing strategy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%