2006
DOI: 10.1016/j.jet.2004.07.008
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Dynamic mechanism design with hidden income and hidden actions

Abstract: We develop general recursive methods to solve for optimal contracts in dynamic principal-agent environments with hidden states and hidden actions. In our baseline model, the principal observes nothing other than transfers. Nevertheless, optimal incentive-constrained insurance can be attained. Starting from a general mechanism with arbitrary communication, randomization, full history dependence, and without restrictions on preferences or technology, we show that the optimal contract can be implemented as a recu… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
19
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 76 publications
(19 citation statements)
references
References 26 publications
(41 reference statements)
0
19
0
Order By: Relevance
“…(ii) Assets eliminate the insurer's ability to smooth the agent's consumption beyond self-insurance (Allen, 1985, andCole andKocherlakota, 2001). Or (iii) the environment becomes highly intractable (Fernandes andPhelan, 2000, andDoepke andTownsend, 2006). In contrast, we show that Markov-perfect insurance contracts result in simple dynamic programs with a single scalar state variable and avoid the curse of dimensionality, including the case with noncontractible savings.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 84%
“…(ii) Assets eliminate the insurer's ability to smooth the agent's consumption beyond self-insurance (Allen, 1985, andCole andKocherlakota, 2001). Or (iii) the environment becomes highly intractable (Fernandes andPhelan, 2000, andDoepke andTownsend, 2006). In contrast, we show that Markov-perfect insurance contracts result in simple dynamic programs with a single scalar state variable and avoid the curse of dimensionality, including the case with noncontractible savings.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 84%
“…Certainly, some existing literature studied optimal dynamic taxation in the framework with hidden types, i.e., either the economic agent or the government has private information, requiring that incentive-compatible constraint met based on the revelation principle (see, Doepke and Townsend, 2006). As a consequence, there the tax policies play the role of implementation schemes, that is, implementing efficient allocations as a competitive equilibrium with truth-telling.…”
Section: Figure 6 Sequential Moves and Equilibrium Derivationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A problem with that approach arises from possible non-convexities induced by the incentive or commitment constraints. 15 Here, by way of contrast we operate in extremely general environments, following Fernandes and Phelan (2000) and Doepke and Townsend (2006). Our linear programming approach can be applied for any preference and technology specifications since, by construction, it convexifies the problem by allowing any possible randomization (lotteries) over the solution variables.…”
Section: Computationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Because of the dynamic adverse selection problem in k , following Fernandes and Phelan (2000) and Doepke and Townsend (2006), 1 the proper state variable in the recursive representation of this problem is not as scalar (as in the MH regime) but a promised utility schedule, w ≡ { w ( k 1 ), w ( k 2 ), …, w ( k # K )} belonging to some set of schedules W (to be determined) where k 1 , k 2 , etc. are the elements of the grid K .…”
Section: 1 Moral Hazard With Unobserved Capital and Investmentmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation