1997
DOI: 10.2307/2111712
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Electoral Institutions, Cleavage Structures, and the Number of Parties

Abstract: Electoral Institutions, Cleavage Structures, and the Number of Parties Theory: A classic question in political science concems ",hat deteImines the number of parties that compete in a given polity. Broadly speaking, there are two approaches to answering this question, one that emphasizes the role of electorallaws in structuring coalitional incentives, another that emphasizes the importance of pre-existing social cleavages. In tbis paper, we view the number of parties as a product of the interaction between the… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

8
294
2
30

Year Published

1999
1999
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
4

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 577 publications
(334 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
8
294
2
30
Order By: Relevance
“…23 The empirical analysis demonstrates that the logic of strategic coordination predicts the number of parties only in democratic settings (see Table 3). In these settings, district magnitude increases the number of parties when many ethnopolitical groups exist and are geographically concentrated, a finding consistent with the party-systems literature (Cox, 1997;Neto & Cox, 1997;Ordeshook & Shvetsova, 1994). In contrast, strategic coordination does not account for the number of parties in nondemocratic settings.…”
Section: Resultssupporting
confidence: 75%
“…23 The empirical analysis demonstrates that the logic of strategic coordination predicts the number of parties only in democratic settings (see Table 3). In these settings, district magnitude increases the number of parties when many ethnopolitical groups exist and are geographically concentrated, a finding consistent with the party-systems literature (Cox, 1997;Neto & Cox, 1997;Ordeshook & Shvetsova, 1994). In contrast, strategic coordination does not account for the number of parties in nondemocratic settings.…”
Section: Resultssupporting
confidence: 75%
“…On the contrary, the adoption of PR followed the formation of fragmented but cohesive political parties (derived from previous social cleavages) (Rokkan 1970, Sartori 1966) -a fact in line with our previous discussion. Moreover, PR encourages higher levels of party fragmentation (Taagapera and Shugart 1989, Ordeshook and Shvestova 1994, Neto and Cox 1997. If, according to collective action theory, the multiplication of (non-encompassing) groups eventually leads to suboptimal results, such as higher transactions costs, distributional coalitions and lower social welfare (Olson 1982), PR cannot be said to reduce rent-seeking behavior.…”
Section: Trade and Proportional Representationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The threshold of inclusion (Tincl), which depends on the average number of parties that are assumed to run in each district, is equal to the highest of one of the following figures: (1) the legal threshold (that is, the legally stipulated minimum 20 Taagapera and Shugart (1989), Ordeshook and Shvetsova (1994) and Amorim Neto and Cox (1997) employ instead the measure of 'effective magnitude'. Since the effective threshold is the reverse of the effective magnitude, both measures should be seen as "two sides of the same coin."…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In contrast, plurality constrains the natural state of party competition and reduces party system fragmentation (Clark and Golder 2006;Amorim-Neto and Cox 1997).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%