2016
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2896321
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Eliciting Strategies in Indefinitely Repeated Games of Strategic Substitutes and Complements

Abstract: We introduce a novel method to elicit strategies in indefinitely repeated games and apply it to games of strategic substitutes and complements. We find that out of 256 possible unit recall machines (and 1024 full strategies) participants could use, only five machines are used more than 5 percent of the time. Those are "static Nash", "myopic best response", "Tit-for-Tat" and two "Nash reversion" strategies. We compare outcome data with "hot" treatments and find that the fact that we elicit strategies did not af… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 8 publications
(4 citation statements)
references
References 18 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Rational bargainers pretend to be obstinate to derive more favorable deal, hence an inefficient delay may arise in equilibrium (Myerson, 1991;Abreu and Gul, 2000). Embrey et al (2017) report experimental evidence consistent with the theoretical predictions about inefficient delay in reputational bargaining. Compte and Jehiel (2002) show that the existence of an outside option may cancel such effect of obstinacy.…”
Section: Obstinacy In Reputational Bargainingmentioning
confidence: 84%
“…Rational bargainers pretend to be obstinate to derive more favorable deal, hence an inefficient delay may arise in equilibrium (Myerson, 1991;Abreu and Gul, 2000). Embrey et al (2017) report experimental evidence consistent with the theoretical predictions about inefficient delay in reputational bargaining. Compte and Jehiel (2002) show that the existence of an outside option may cancel such effect of obstinacy.…”
Section: Obstinacy In Reputational Bargainingmentioning
confidence: 84%
“…In other words, in the FRD setting, the introduction of Payback downsizes the role of TFT and restores the ability of equilibrium conditions and risk dominance to predict cooperation also with imperfect monitoring. A number of other experiments have reported an important role for TFT in categorizing behavior (for example, Bigoni et al, 2013;Fréchette, 2011, 2019;Dvorak and Fehrler, 2018;Embrey et al, 2016;Romero and Rosokha, 2019) and Payback can offer a new perspective on their results. In general, Payback has been overlooked in the empirical literature.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Although the strategies are now directly observable, subjects' behavior may be influenced by the strategies presented in the set. In the third approach, which we take, players construct strategies from scratch (Bruttel and Kamecke, 2012;Embrey, Mengel, and Peeters, 2016;Dal Bó and Fréchette, 2017;Romero and Rosokha, 2016). An advantage of our interface is that there are minimal restrictions on the types and lengths of pure strategies.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%