2005
DOI: 10.5840/pom20055221
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Employment Struggles and the Commodification of Time: Marx and the Analysis of Working Time Flexibility

Abstract: This paper explores new working time arrangements around a critique of the 'commodification of time' to illuminate the contradictions of such new flexibilities. Two features of these new arrangements are seen as relevant for evaluating the Marx/Engels analysis. Firstly, those arguing the commodification of time represent all [can you suggest a wording that will make clear what this 'all' refers to?] having become a commodity outside of the processes of exchange for labour power. Significantly -and central in a… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
10
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
0
10
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Conversely, those in work experience an intensification of work: workers are pushed to produce more within less time to increase their efficiency and maximise profits (Everingham, 2002). In the name of flexibility, employers have sought to control more of the worker’s time, removed temporal protections, and encouraged self-regulation in work contracts (Rubery et al, 2005; Tuckman, 2005) to fuel the capitalistic drive for productivity and efficiency. The worker is thus expected to offer constant availability to supply and produce while there is demand; to fail to do so indicated inefficiency and a lost opportunity for profit.…”
Section: Vulnerability In An Economic Contextmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Conversely, those in work experience an intensification of work: workers are pushed to produce more within less time to increase their efficiency and maximise profits (Everingham, 2002). In the name of flexibility, employers have sought to control more of the worker’s time, removed temporal protections, and encouraged self-regulation in work contracts (Rubery et al, 2005; Tuckman, 2005) to fuel the capitalistic drive for productivity and efficiency. The worker is thus expected to offer constant availability to supply and produce while there is demand; to fail to do so indicated inefficiency and a lost opportunity for profit.…”
Section: Vulnerability In An Economic Contextmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the other hand, we claim that the feature of not being accumulative is distinctly special for time since time can never be accumulated, not even a little. Recent technological developments such as devices making it possible to work remotely as well as more flexible working arrangements than the traditional norm have contributed to the perception that time is something that can be saved (Tuckman 2005). Nevertheless, in reality, there is simply no way to actually save time; time can only be instantaneously reallocated to other activities.…”
Section: Non-accumulativitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This has significant implications for pay levels as it renders statutory or voluntary minimum hourly pay rates ineffectual (Moore, 2014). In addition to securing low pay, this leads not only to the intensification and extensification of working time (Hayes and Moore, 2014), but also facilitates the shifting boundaries between commodified and de-commodified time (Tuckman, 2005). As such, the proliferation of ZHCs is a significant element of the proliferation of unpaid labour in the UK economy, and is a significant facilitating factor of the low-pay economy.…”
Section: The Emergence Of the Neoliberal Organizationmentioning
confidence: 99%