1993
DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198203575.001.0001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Entrepreneurial Politics in Mid-Victorian Britain

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

1994
1994
2014
2014

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 70 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Both the concepts of CSR and corporate philanthropy often are traced to the Industrial Revolution, when individual business owners invested in the well‐being of their staff to improve productivity and achieve greater social goals (Searle, ; Lee, ). Such strategies were uncommon, and early attempts to engender CSR were viewed as incompatible with capitalism by shareholders, courts, and commentators (Cochran, ).…”
Section: Contemporary Csr and Corporate Philanthropymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Both the concepts of CSR and corporate philanthropy often are traced to the Industrial Revolution, when individual business owners invested in the well‐being of their staff to improve productivity and achieve greater social goals (Searle, ; Lee, ). Such strategies were uncommon, and early attempts to engender CSR were viewed as incompatible with capitalism by shareholders, courts, and commentators (Cochran, ).…”
Section: Contemporary Csr and Corporate Philanthropymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The alternative, he implied, was that pressures for reform might become overwhelming, as they had in France (see Schonhard-Bailey, 2006). In sum, repeal was an attempt to moderate the mounting pressures for parliamentary reform: by satisfying the middle class and industrialists with repeal, their drive to gain control of parliamentary seats would wane and, moreover, the working-class Chartist movement (seeking more radical reform of Parliament) would lose momentum (see Searle, 1993;and Schonhard-Bailey, 2006). In terms of our model, the protectionist aristocracy, by partially transferring control over the government to the pro-free-trade industrialists (the Reform Act of 1832) and allowing a switch in trade policy (the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846), placated the populace, thereby convincing it to relinquish its more radical demands.…”
Section: Great Britain In the Nineteenth Centurymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the one hand, Great Britain moved toward free trade in 1846 (with the repeal of the Corn Laws) before becoming a democracy. The repeal of the Corn Laws undercutt the economic interests of the ruling landed aristocracy, proved that industrialists were gaining control of Parliament, and placated the working-class Chartist movement, which was seeking a more radical reform of Parliament (see Searle, 1993, andSchonhard-Bailey, 2006). Thereafter, Great Britain had a stable free-trade policy throughout its transition to a fully consolidated democracy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the other hand, if democratization leads to aut(s), l always prefers to transfer the control of the autocracy to s the first time that µ t = µ, since it makes no sense for l to democratize for the sole purpose of postponing the arrival of aut(s). 3 Suppose thatφ 3 ≤ ϕ < min λφ2 (λ), wherē Then, from (32) and (33), if l democratizes the first that time µ t = µ, then, no matter what policy is implemented by N , a coup is always a possibility. Thus, democracy cannot be semi-consolidated, and the most that N can do is to influence which elite group controls the autocracy after the coup.…”
Section: Proof Of Proposition 2 Parts a And Bmentioning
confidence: 99%