1984
DOI: 10.1016/0047-2727(84)90012-4
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Equilibrium among local jurisdictions: toward an integrated treatment of voting and residential choice

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
155
0
3

Year Published

1996
1996
2010
2010

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 242 publications
(160 citation statements)
references
References 6 publications
2
155
0
3
Order By: Relevance
“…However, if preferred expenditure and home value were negatively correlated, NYSTAR will tend to exacerbate these differences in preferences. Though the empirical evidence is mixed (see, for example, Gramlich and Rubinfeld, 1982), home value and spending preferences are typically assumed to be positively correlated in theoretical models of local public finance (e.g., Epple et al, 1984;Calabrese et al, 2008). However, whether progressive fiscal incentives lead to larger changes in district spending is an empirical question.…”
Section: Did the Impact Of Nystar Vary With The Distribution Of Tax Rmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, if preferred expenditure and home value were negatively correlated, NYSTAR will tend to exacerbate these differences in preferences. Though the empirical evidence is mixed (see, for example, Gramlich and Rubinfeld, 1982), home value and spending preferences are typically assumed to be positively correlated in theoretical models of local public finance (e.g., Epple et al, 1984;Calabrese et al, 2008). However, whether progressive fiscal incentives lead to larger changes in district spending is an empirical question.…”
Section: Did the Impact Of Nystar Vary With The Distribution Of Tax Rmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In multi-community models with migration costs, we get the well-known strati…cation result, going back to Tiebout (1956). Citizens with similar preferences for taxes and government spending or public good provision group together in one jurisdiction (see, e.g., Epple and Romer, 1991, Epple, Filimon, and Romer, 1984, Fernandez and Rogerson, 1996, Glomm and Laguno¤, 1998, Hansen and Kessler 2001b, or Nechyba, 1997. Implicitly, 2 An exception is Hindricks (2001) who analyzes the case where the poor are more mobile.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…8 Its mean is given by = R "g(")d". We do not have to specify variance and skewness of g("), as we have the same distribution for each income group of citizens.…”
Section: Voting On the Welfare State: Migrationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…5 The longer-run impact was to create a system of "grand-fathered" tax rates for houses based on historical prices. The associated tax savings can be substantial: Considering the one quarter of San Francisco Bay Area families with more than 20 years of housing tenure in 1 Much of the intuition on household sorting was derived from a long line of theoretical work in local public finance that started in Tiebout (1956), and which includes Epple and Zelenitz (1981), Epple, Filimon, andRomer (1984, 1993), Benabou (1993), Fernandez and Rogerson (1996), Nechyba (1997) and Epple and Sieg (1999). 2 Recent examples are found in Barrow and Rouse (2004), Rothstein (2006) and Bajari and Kahn (2005).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%