2014
DOI: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2014.04.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Estimating potential output in developing countries

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

0
6
0
1

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(9 citation statements)
references
References 3 publications
0
6
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…where GDP is gross domestic product, K is the capital stock, L is labor employed, TFP represents total factor productivity (TFP), α is the income share of capital (assumed to be 0.3), and the subscript t denotes time. 2 This paper's measure of labor differs from that of Burns et al (2014) by using labor market data (labor force participation, sectoral employment, and unemployment) produced by the International Labour Organization to measure labor inputs. 3 Burns et al (2014) and other earlier work used the working-age population as an alternative proxy.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…where GDP is gross domestic product, K is the capital stock, L is labor employed, TFP represents total factor productivity (TFP), α is the income share of capital (assumed to be 0.3), and the subscript t denotes time. 2 This paper's measure of labor differs from that of Burns et al (2014) by using labor market data (labor force participation, sectoral employment, and unemployment) produced by the International Labour Organization to measure labor inputs. 3 Burns et al (2014) and other earlier work used the working-age population as an alternative proxy.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2 This paper's measure of labor differs from that of Burns et al (2014) by using labor market data (labor force participation, sectoral employment, and unemployment) produced by the International Labour Organization to measure labor inputs. 3 Burns et al (2014) and other earlier work used the working-age population as an alternative proxy. It is recognized that the labor market data capture labor market behavior imperfectly, especially in economies characterized by a sizable informal labor sector.…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…* is the natural rate of unemployment (usually determined using the equilibrium solution to labor demand and labor supply); LFPR is the labor force participation rate; LF 1564 is the working-age population; and K is the capital stock (calculated using the perpetual inventory method). The share of labor, α, is set to 0.7, a standard assumption (see Burns et al 2014). We use this simplifying assumption because of the difficulty of obtaining the share of labor income in Iraq's nonoil GDP.…”
Section: Annex 2b: Potential Gdp Calculationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A large literature, using varying samples, also finds that both cyclical and structural factors have contributed to the post-crisis EM growth slowdown. 14 11 GDP is assumed to be characterized by a Cobb-Douglas production function of total factor productivity, labor proxied by employment, and the capital stock derived using the perpetual inventory method, assuming a labor share of national income of 0.7 (Burns et al 2014). Total factor productivity is derived as the residual.…”
Section: Slowing Productivity Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Potential labor input growth is thus calculated as the growth rate in working age population. The stock of capital is constructed using a simplified version of the perpetual inventory methodology from investment data, assuming a depreciation rate of 7 percent (IMF 2005;Burns et al 2014). Implicitly, this assumes that there are no shifts over time in the productivity of investment, e.g.…”
Section: Slowing Productivity Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%