2006
DOI: 10.1007/s00285-005-0369-8
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Evolutionary game dynamics in a Wright-Fisher process

Abstract: Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations can be described by a frequency dependent, stochastic Wright-Fisher process. We consider a symmetric game between two strategies, A and B. There are discrete generations. In each generation, individuals produce offspring proportional to their payoff. The next generation is sampled randomly from this pool of offspring. The total population size is constant. The resulting Markov process has two absorbing states corresponding to homogeneous populations of all A or … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
5

Citation Types

4
222
0

Year Published

2006
2006
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
4
2
1

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 225 publications
(226 citation statements)
references
References 22 publications
4
222
0
Order By: Relevance
“…For detailed reviews of the replicator equation and other approaches to evolutionary game dynamics, see Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), Weibull (1995), Samuelson (1997), Cressman (2003), Sigmund (1998, 2003), Gintis (2000) and Nowak and Sigmund (2004). in finite populations Imhof and Nowak, 2006;Taylor et al, 2004;Fudenberg et al, 2006;Traulsen et al, 2006a,b), in spatially extended systems (Nowak and May, 1992;Nakamaru et al, 1998;Killingback and Doebeli, 1996;van Baalen and Rand, 1998;Irwin and Taylor, 2001;Hauert and Doebeli, 2004;Ifti et al, 2004;Nakamaru and Iwasa, 2005;Jansen and van Baalen, 2006) or on graphs (Lieberman et al, 2005;Santos et al, , 2006a. Taylor and Nowak (2006) analyze a scenario where the interaction rate does depend on the strategies.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For detailed reviews of the replicator equation and other approaches to evolutionary game dynamics, see Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), Weibull (1995), Samuelson (1997), Cressman (2003), Sigmund (1998, 2003), Gintis (2000) and Nowak and Sigmund (2004). in finite populations Imhof and Nowak, 2006;Taylor et al, 2004;Fudenberg et al, 2006;Traulsen et al, 2006a,b), in spatially extended systems (Nowak and May, 1992;Nakamaru et al, 1998;Killingback and Doebeli, 1996;van Baalen and Rand, 1998;Irwin and Taylor, 2001;Hauert and Doebeli, 2004;Ifti et al, 2004;Nakamaru and Iwasa, 2005;Jansen and van Baalen, 2006) or on graphs (Lieberman et al, 2005;Santos et al, , 2006a. Taylor and Nowak (2006) analyze a scenario where the interaction rate does depend on the strategies.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Game theory, in which only selfish behaviors will be rewarded, shares the common dilemma as the evolution of cooperation in nature. Therefore, during the last few decades, game theory has been a central tool for understanding the origin of cooperation (Maynard Smith, 1982;Weibull, 1995;Hofbauer and Sigmund, 1998;Nowak and Sigmund, 2004;Nowak, 2006). Actually, there are a variety of game-theoretic models used to analyze cooperative dilemma, such as Prisoner's dilemma (PD) game, snow-drift (SD) game (or Hawk-dove game), and public goods games.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Over the past few decades, several mechanisms have been proposed to successfully overcome the dilemma. Nowak (2006) reviewed the related studies and categorized there mechanisms as five rules: kin selection, direct reciprocity, indirect reciprocity, network reciprocity, and group selection. Generally, any game-theoretic E-mail address: gaomeng03@hotmail.com. model of cooperative evolution will be related to the five rules.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations