2010
DOI: 10.1016/j.jeem.2009.11.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Expected net present value, expected net future value, and the Ramsey rule

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
5

Citation Types

2
43
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
3
2
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 45 publications
(45 citation statements)
references
References 19 publications
2
43
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This paper also makes methodological improvements on previous explanations for the puzzle. In contrast to Gollier (2009a), Gollier (2009b) and Buchholz and Schumacher (2009), the social planner remains risk neutral within the economy of this paper. This is consistent with the original paradox and shows that there is no requirement to call on risk aversion to resolve the problem.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 81%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…This paper also makes methodological improvements on previous explanations for the puzzle. In contrast to Gollier (2009a), Gollier (2009b) and Buchholz and Schumacher (2009), the social planner remains risk neutral within the economy of this paper. This is consistent with the original paradox and shows that there is no requirement to call on risk aversion to resolve the problem.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 81%
“…This contrasts with Gollier (2004): "Clearly, Weitzman and I cannot be both right. In fact, to tell the truth, I believe that we are both wrong" (p.88), Hepburn and Groom (2007): "Our conclusion, perhaps surprisingly, is that Weitzman and Gollier are both right" (p.107), Gollier (2009a): "This demonstrates that, as suggested by Hepburn and Groom (2007), both Weitzman (1998) and Gollier (2004) are right" (p.6), Gollier (2009b): "In a sense, contrary to our conclusion in Gollier (2004), both Weitzman (1998) and Gollier (2004) are right..." (p.8) and Buchholz and Schumacher (2009): "Much more is in favor of Gollier's approach because he puts the risk to the right place, i.e. to the future period" (p.4).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The steps involved in applying the NPV [1][2][3] rule to evaluate an investment proposal are summarized in this paper. Tow inputs are required to calculate a project's NPV: (1) the expected cash-flow stream that the project will generate over its useful life and (2) the appropriate cost of capital that reflects the risk of the expected cash-flows.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Part of the debate is still centered on justifying why hyperbolic discounting should be considered a rational way to form intertemporal preferences, more than exponential discounting. Prelec (2004), Dimitri (2005), Drouhin (2009), Farmer and Geanakoplos (2009), and Gollier (2010) argue that hyperbolic discounting is time consistent and rational. Decreasing impatience in a stochastic environment allows for a formal proof of such claim.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%