2014
DOI: 10.1007/s11127-014-0176-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Explaining variation in the competitiveness of U.S. Senate elections, 1922–2004

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
3
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
4
1
1

Relationship

4
2

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(4 citation statements)
references
References 55 publications
1
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This is exactly the empirical pattern that Winer, Kenny, and Grofman (2014) find for U.S. Senate elections between 1922 and 2004: For a range of moderate states (i.e., a range of states with a PVI relatively close to zero), the estimated marginal effect of a state’s PVI on the vote difference between Democrats and Republicans is close to zero, while this marginal effect is much larger for states that are outside this range.…”
Section: Empirical Implicationssupporting
confidence: 79%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This is exactly the empirical pattern that Winer, Kenny, and Grofman (2014) find for U.S. Senate elections between 1922 and 2004: For a range of moderate states (i.e., a range of states with a PVI relatively close to zero), the estimated marginal effect of a state’s PVI on the vote difference between Democrats and Republicans is close to zero, while this marginal effect is much larger for states that are outside this range.…”
Section: Empirical Implicationssupporting
confidence: 79%
“… 1 See Table 1 in Winer, Kenny, and Grofman (2014) for evidence that a significant share of U.S. Senate elections are noncompetitive. In 29.4% of U.S. Senate elections between 1922 and 2004 without an incumbent running, the winner received a vote share that was at least 20 percentage points larger than the loser’s vote share.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There are at least three reasons: (1) Parties impose constraints on themselves to preserve their credibility and coherence and to cater to donors (Demsetz 1982;Levy 2004;Roemer 2001). When circumstances change, some parties can adapt their programs faster than others; (2) In electoral systems with individual electoral districts, parties impose constraints on their local candidates to protect their national reputation, a situation studied by Austen-Smith (1987), Callander (2005), Winer, Kenny, and Grofman (2014), and others. This tether prevents local candidates from situating their own platforms close to their major opponent if this involves a substantial departure from the national party platform.…”
Section: Political Competitivenessmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In other words, as the parties become more sharply differentiated, Democratic (Republican) candidates in constituencies with a right (left) of center median voter find it harder to compete successfully, since they will not be able to convincingly offer a position close to that constituency's median voter. The nature of the constraints will affect which seats are competitive and which are not (Winer et al, 2014). Moreover, when the party's legislative incumbents are more homogeneous ideologically, it is much easier for activists to seek to enforce ideological conformity on party candidates and to threaten to run opponents if they do not toe the party line.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%