2004
DOI: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2003.08.003
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Exploring social welfare functions and violation of monotonicity: an example from inequalities in health

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

1
38
0

Year Published

2007
2007
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

3
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 44 publications
(39 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
1
38
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Andersson and Lyttkens (1999) reported a median marginal trade-off varying from 0.11 to 0.35 years of life expectancy among the worst off in exchange for 1 year lost among the best off in society, whereas this median was 0.45 in Johannesson and Gerdtham (1996). Abasolo and Tsuchiya (2004;2013) even found that people sometimes violate monotonicity in order to achieve a more equitable distribution; i.e., they sometimes prefer an outcome where all beneficiaries receive less but with a smaller difference between them.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…Andersson and Lyttkens (1999) reported a median marginal trade-off varying from 0.11 to 0.35 years of life expectancy among the worst off in exchange for 1 year lost among the best off in society, whereas this median was 0.45 in Johannesson and Gerdtham (1996). Abasolo and Tsuchiya (2004;2013) even found that people sometimes violate monotonicity in order to achieve a more equitable distribution; i.e., they sometimes prefer an outcome where all beneficiaries receive less but with a smaller difference between them.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…In other words, the final distribution of health could mean less health for both groups, so long as the inequality narrows. Again, such responses generate pathological social welfare functions in standard economics terms, but to us, and as we have argued elsewhere (Abasolo and Tsuchiya, 2004), are entirely plausible, particularly if health is seen as a pre-requisite for us to flourish as individuals (Anand, 2002, Culyer, 1971, Culyer, 1989. Median in bold * This implies a backward bending iso-welfare contour.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 85%
“…For instance, Dolan et al has found that up to 20% of those interviewed had such preferences (Dolan et al, 2002). Such perceptions support a backward bending social welfare contour (Abasolo and Tsuchiya, 2004), which allows for the possibility that a move due north from certain points is associated with an inferior contour, because it implies moving away from 45 degree diagonal through the origin O. So this is another example of a conflict between a social welfare judgement placed within the gains space, and a social welfare judgement placed within the outcomes space.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…Recently in this journal Abasolo and Tsuchiya (2004) (henceforth AT) argued that the HRSWF need not satisfy the monotonicity property (also know as the Pareto criteria) if the HRSWF is made averse to health inequality to the full extent. They propose a new HRSWF which violates monotonicity but seemingly is better at accounting for inequality.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…
In a recent paper in this journal Abasolo and Tsuchiya [Abasolo, I., Tsuchiya, A., 2004. Exploring social welfare functions and violation of monotonicity: an example from inequalities in health.
…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%