2010
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1647311
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Financial Choice in a Non-Ricardian Model of Trade

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

1
3
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
3
1

Relationship

0
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 4 publications
(4 citation statements)
references
References 31 publications
1
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…To illustrate the relationship between the micro and macro effects of relative cost shocks across countries, such as a small movement in the nominal exchange rate (see Burstein, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2005) for a discussion contrasting the impact of large versus small shocks on the real exchange rate), Table 1 lists the volatility of the terms of trade relative to the real exchange rate in U.S. data alongside results from simulated data for small cost shocks in our model. 20 We see in the table that the model delivers a variance in the terms of trade that is approximately one-half the variance of the real exchange rate when d = 1.5, between our lower-bound for trade costs of 1.25 from the survey by Russ and Valderrama (2010) and the higher value for trade costs (1.74) estimated by Anderson and van Wincoop (2004). This ratio of volatilities corresponds with the figure reported for the U.S. in Corsetti, Dedola, and Leduc (2008).…”
Section: Export Price Rigidity and Macroeconomic Volatilitysupporting
confidence: 70%
“…To illustrate the relationship between the micro and macro effects of relative cost shocks across countries, such as a small movement in the nominal exchange rate (see Burstein, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2005) for a discussion contrasting the impact of large versus small shocks on the real exchange rate), Table 1 lists the volatility of the terms of trade relative to the real exchange rate in U.S. data alongside results from simulated data for small cost shocks in our model. 20 We see in the table that the model delivers a variance in the terms of trade that is approximately one-half the variance of the real exchange rate when d = 1.5, between our lower-bound for trade costs of 1.25 from the survey by Russ and Valderrama (2010) and the higher value for trade costs (1.74) estimated by Anderson and van Wincoop (2004). This ratio of volatilities corresponds with the figure reported for the U.S. in Corsetti, Dedola, and Leduc (2008).…”
Section: Export Price Rigidity and Macroeconomic Volatilitysupporting
confidence: 70%
“…1 Comparative statics based on Column 4 in Table2.2 2 All other results in the paper are also robust to including only one of the two interaction terms at a time.2 3 In unreported results, I have con…rmed that my …ndings are not driven by …nancially underdeveloped countries having systematically lower or higher real exchange rates. SeeRuss and Valderrama (2009) on the link between …nancial development and real exchange rates in general equilibrium.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A higher openness induces exporters to be more profitable, which finally allows them to borrow cheaply. Russ and Valderrama (2009) demonstrate how an increased trade openness can induce a better access to financial markets so that for countries more open to trade a bigger credit sector is likely to be associated with higher current account surpluses.…”
Section: Trade Openness and Current Account Imbalances: What Are The mentioning
confidence: 92%