Abstract:In many countries wages are set in two stages, where industry-level collective bargaining is followed by …rm-speci…c arrangements determining actual paid wages as a markup on the industry wage ‡oor. What explains the wage set in each of these stages? In this paper we show that both the industry wage ‡oor and the average wage cushion are systematically associated with the degree of …rm heterogeneity in the industry: The former (latter) is negatively (positively) associated with the productivity spread. Furtherm… Show more
“… The expression ‘wage cushion’, which seems to have been coined by Olivier Blanchard, has come into use recently in order to overcome certain ambiguities (see Bastos et al ., 2009; Cardoso and Portugal, 2005). The older literature often uses the expressions ‘wage drift’ (see, e.g.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“… See, e.g. Holden (1990, 1998), Holmlund and Skedinger (1990), Pehkonen and Viskari (1994), and Hibbs and Locking (1996) for the Nordic countries, Lupi and Ordine (1993) and Ordine (1996) for Italy, Cardoso and Portugal (2005) and Bastos et al . (2009) for Portugal, Palenzuela and Jimeno (1996) for Spain, and Meyer (1994) and Bellmann and Kohaut (1995) for western Germany. …”
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Terms of use:
Documents in
“… The expression ‘wage cushion’, which seems to have been coined by Olivier Blanchard, has come into use recently in order to overcome certain ambiguities (see Bastos et al ., 2009; Cardoso and Portugal, 2005). The older literature often uses the expressions ‘wage drift’ (see, e.g.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“… See, e.g. Holden (1990, 1998), Holmlund and Skedinger (1990), Pehkonen and Viskari (1994), and Hibbs and Locking (1996) for the Nordic countries, Lupi and Ordine (1993) and Ordine (1996) for Italy, Cardoso and Portugal (2005) and Bastos et al . (2009) for Portugal, Palenzuela and Jimeno (1996) for Spain, and Meyer (1994) and Bellmann and Kohaut (1995) for western Germany. …”
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Terms of use:
Documents in
Using a …xed e¤ects estimator and a dynamic panel data system-GMM estimator on a sample of 77 banks, covering the period 1988-2005, this paper estimates how wages in the Portuguese banking sector depend on the employers'ability to pay. The results indicate that wages are strongly positively correlated with rents even after controlling for …rm and workforce characteristics. A conservative Lester's range of wages due to rent sharing is around 56% of the mean wage of the Portuguese banking sector, a number that is considerably larger than in previous studies.
“…In the Egger–Kreickemeier model, more productive firms pay higher wages at the rate . The speed at which wage rates rise as productivity rises in markets with heterogeneous firms is, of course, an empirical matter; see, for example, Bastos, Monteiro, and Straume (). Perhaps it is not a power function.…”
Do firms engaging in international trade have higher or lower profit margins? It is well established that more productive firms engage in trading activities and as a result have higher profit levels. We use two theoretical models (the Melitz model and the Egger–Kreickemeier model) to clarify the relationship between productivity, trade activity, and profit margins and derive three hypotheses: (I) profit margins rise as productivity rises for domestic firms; (II) profit margins rise as productivity rises for trading firms; and (III) profit margins are not higher for trading firms than for domestic firms. We test these hypotheses using detailed micro‐data for Finland (2005–10) and the Netherlands (2002–10). We find strong support for Hypothesis I (in favour of the Melitz model), Hypothesis II (in favour of both models) and Hypothesis III (in favour of the Egger–Kreickemeier model). A propensity score matching analysis provides further support for Hypothesis III.
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.