IntroductionIn a fundamental sense, modern 'development' has been premised on replacing peasantries. Th is has been the case since the appearance of the fi rst monocultures in non-European colonies, 1 and it has informed understandings and theories of development over the last one and a half centuries as factory labour forces and industrial technology have emerged. Since the register of development is the (apparent) 2 absence of peasantries 3 in the Global North, this condition is projected as a universal goal-and has been written into representations of (capitalist and socialist) development from classical political economy through Rostow ( 1960 ) and Barrington Moore ( 1967 ) to contemporary World Bank and Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) publications. Given the substantial agrarian features of the non-European world, its (development) future has been represented as one in which peasantries disappear. 1 C.L.R. James observed that slave labour systems in the Americas prefi gured the fi rst proletariat, insofar as extensive monocultures in Europe were disallowed at the time by guild laws and property relations ( 1963 ). 2 Nevertheless, the USA, UK, France, the Netherlands, and New Zealand have a percentage of small farms in the range of 10-25 % (Hilmi 2012 : 69). 3 'Peasantries' are diverse across time and space, sharing attributes of the 'farm as a place of labour, where… labour is provided by the family and mobilised within the community through relations of reciprocity' (Hilmi 2012 : 25).