1999
DOI: 10.1111/0022-1082.00181
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Home Bias at Home: Local Equity Preference in Domestic Portfolios

Abstract: The strong bias in favor of domestic securities is a well-documented characteristic of international investment portfolios, yet we show that the preference for investing close to home also applies to portfolios of domestic stocks. Specifically, U.S. investment managers exhibit a strong preference for locally headquartered firms, particularly small, highly levered firms that produce nontraded goods. These results suggest that asymmetric information between local and nonlocal investors may drive the preference f… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

69
1,250
7
15

Year Published

2004
2004
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
5
4

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 2,549 publications
(1,341 citation statements)
references
References 51 publications
69
1,250
7
15
Order By: Relevance
“…In their setting, an investor has perfect knowledge about the future value of the security at time T , and thus faces an arbitrage opportunity related to a security, which is modeled as a Brownian Bridge process. 8 This result is consistent with the 3-factor pricing model of Fama and French (see ) in which the factors HML or SMB are functions of the price of the security.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 86%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In their setting, an investor has perfect knowledge about the future value of the security at time T , and thus faces an arbitrage opportunity related to a security, which is modeled as a Brownian Bridge process. 8 This result is consistent with the 3-factor pricing model of Fama and French (see ) in which the factors HML or SMB are functions of the price of the security.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 86%
“…In both cases, it is intuitively clear that the active investors will perceive that both the risk and expected return of the stock will be a function of the current price. 8 The fact that risk and return vary with price, from the standpoint of the active investor, is contrary to standard models such as the CAPM 9 or the Black-Scholes-Merton option 4 Under the assumption of existence of market frictions and imperfections, Basak and Croitoru (2000) show that mispricing can be sustainable in general equilibrium.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 95%
“…For example, if privileged information mainly "trickles down" from the company's headquarters (see Davis and Henderson (2004); Pirinsky and Wang (2006)), one could expect informed trading to concentrate in the market closest to the headquarters. And in fact, Grinblatt and Keloharju (1999) show that Finnish investors' portfolios overweight the stocks of geographically close companies, and Coval and Moskowitz (1999) detect a similar bias in the portfolio choices of US domestic funds. Brennan et al (2005) provide further evidence on the informational disadvantage of foreign investors.…”
Section: Information-based Tradingmentioning
confidence: 94%
“…Even within countries, there is evidence that investors tend to hold stocks of local companies, about which they presumably have more information. For example, Coval and Moskowitz (1999) show that U.S. investment managers exhibit a strong preference for locally-headquartered firms. Each of these studies suggests that asymmetric information between local and non-local investors may be an important factor for investment decisions.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%