2015
DOI: 10.3386/w21667
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

House Prices and Consumer Spending

Abstract: Recent empirical work shows large consumption responses to house price movements. This is at odds with a prominent theoretical view which, using the logic of the permanent income hypothesis, argues that consumption responses should be small. We show that, in contrast to this view, workhorse models of consumption with incomplete markets calibrated to rich crosssectional micro facts actually predict large consumption responses, in line with the data. To explain this result, we show that consumption responses to … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

17
151
1

Year Published

2015
2015
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
4
4
2

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 112 publications
(169 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
17
151
1
Order By: Relevance
“…36 This effect is variously referred to as a wealth effect, an endowment income effect or an endowment effect. Berger et al (2017) distinguish between an endowment income (wealth) effect, an ordinary income effect, a substitution effect and a collateral effect in the transmission of house prices to consumption. Year of the boom.…”
Section: Consumptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…36 This effect is variously referred to as a wealth effect, an endowment income effect or an endowment effect. Berger et al (2017) distinguish between an endowment income (wealth) effect, an ordinary income effect, a substitution effect and a collateral effect in the transmission of house prices to consumption. Year of the boom.…”
Section: Consumptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…10 The empirical value of Mian et al's estimates is that they are quite informative about the "consumption block" of macroeconomic models. They strongly reject simple complete markets models of consumption such as the influential model of Sinai and Souleles (2005)-in which the elasticity of consumption to house prices is zero-in favor of models with life-cycle effects, uninsurable income risk, borrowing constraints, and in which households can substitute away from housing when its price rises (see, e.g., Berger et al (2017) for a discussion of such a model). This latter class of models has quite different implications about the effects of macroeconomic policies such as fiscal and monetary policy-but also housing policy-than the former class of models.…”
Section: Causal Effects As Identified Momentsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As a final note, while Berger, Guerrieri, Lorenzoni, and Vavra (2015) use a fully rational framework to derive equation 6, it is useful to note that marginal propensities to consume may vary across the population due to behavioral biases such as hyperbolic discounting in addition to borrowing constraints (see Harris and Laibson (2001)). …”
Section: Models Most Closely Related To These Factsmentioning
confidence: 99%