1992
DOI: 10.1016/0895-7177(92)90085-y
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

How hard is it to control an election?

Abstract: Some voting schemes that are in principle susceptible to control are nevertheless resistant in practice due to excessive computational costs; others are vulnerable. We illustrate this in detail for plurality voting and for Condorcet voting.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
304
0

Year Published

1997
1997
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
4
4

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 263 publications
(304 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
0
304
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Campaign management comprises all sorts of activities for influencing the outcome of an election, including well-known scenarios such as bribery (Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra, & Hemaspaandra, 2009;Dorn & Schlotter, 2012;Schlotter, Elkind, & Faliszewski, 2011;Elkind, Faliszewski, & Slinko, 2012) and control (Bartholdi III, Tovey, & Trick, 1992;Elkind, Faliszewski, & Slinko, 2011;Erdélyi, Piras, & Rothe, 2011). While these works relate to campaigning in case of classical voting scenarios where one typically wants to make a specific candidate win or to prevent him from winning, Christian, Fellows, Rosamond, and Slinko (2007) introduced the scenario of lobbying in multiple referenda.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Campaign management comprises all sorts of activities for influencing the outcome of an election, including well-known scenarios such as bribery (Faliszewski, Hemaspaandra, & Hemaspaandra, 2009;Dorn & Schlotter, 2012;Schlotter, Elkind, & Faliszewski, 2011;Elkind, Faliszewski, & Slinko, 2012) and control (Bartholdi III, Tovey, & Trick, 1992;Elkind, Faliszewski, & Slinko, 2011;Erdélyi, Piras, & Rothe, 2011). While these works relate to campaigning in case of classical voting scenarios where one typically wants to make a specific candidate win or to prevent him from winning, Christian, Fellows, Rosamond, and Slinko (2007) introduced the scenario of lobbying in multiple referenda.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…WMM is NP-hard even for the case of a single element in the universe. 2 There is a name clash between the literature on covering problems and that on elections. In the former, "weights" refer to what voting literature would call "prices."…”
Section: Examplementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Definition 1 (Bartholdi et al [2], Faliszewski et al [12,21]). In each of the problems Approval-$BRIBERY (priced bribery), Approval-$CCAV (priced control by adding voters), and Approval-$CCDV (priced control by deleting voters), we are given an approval election E = (C, V ) with C = {p, c 1 , .…”
Section: From Approval Voting To Covering Problemsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This paradox is closely related to Arrow's independence of irrelevant alternatives [2]: Arrow postulated that for any reasonable form of preference aggregation the relative collective ranking of two alternatives should only depend on their relative rankings provided by the individuals, and not on any third ("irrelevant") alternative. Our example demonstrates that the Borda rule, when used as an aggregator for preference orders, violates this desideratum: the relative ranking of A and B adopted by the collective does depend on C. Our paradox also has close connections to the topic of election control by means of adding (or deleting) candidates, widely studied in computational social choice [4,9], which in turn relies on violations of Arrow's independence axiom: our example demonstrates how adding candidate C to a Borda election in which B was winning can result in A becoming the new winner.…”
Section: The Paradox Of Late Collective Uncertainty Resolutionmentioning
confidence: 85%