2007
DOI: 10.1016/j.jedc.2006.10.002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

How important is discount rate heterogeneity for wealth inequality?

Abstract: This paper investigates the role of discount rate heterogeneity for wealth inequality. The key idea is to infer the distribution of preference parameters from the observed age profile of wealth inequality. The contribution of preference heterogeneity to wealth inequality can then be measured using a quantitative life-cycle model. I find that discount rate heterogeneity increases the Gini coefficient of wealth by around 0.07 to levels that are close to the data. The share of wealth held by the richest 1% of hou… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

4
61
0

Year Published

2008
2008
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 78 publications
(65 citation statements)
references
References 30 publications
4
61
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We choose the annual time discount rate, = 0:03, the preference parameter for bequests, = 15, the coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion, = 3, the annual risk-free interest rate, r = 1:8%, 26 the annual average return on the risky asset, = 8:8%, which implies that the risk premium of the risky asset is r = 7%, and the volatility of return of the risky asset, = 0:26. 27 As in 25 Of course, we need to check whether the kernel given in Proposition 5 satis…es some boundary conditions of f (x) at x . See the discussion of boundary conditions in Section 4.…”
Section: The Calibrated Economymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We choose the annual time discount rate, = 0:03, the preference parameter for bequests, = 15, the coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion, = 3, the annual risk-free interest rate, r = 1:8%, 26 the annual average return on the risky asset, = 8:8%, which implies that the risk premium of the risky asset is r = 7%, and the volatility of return of the risky asset, = 0:26. 27 As in 25 Of course, we need to check whether the kernel given in Proposition 5 satis…es some boundary conditions of f (x) at x . See the discussion of boundary conditions in Section 4.…”
Section: The Calibrated Economymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Preference heterogeneity has also become a salient issue in mainstream macroeconomics. For instance, Krusell and Smith, Jr. (1998), Coen-Pirani (2004), De Nardi (2004, Guvenen (2006), Hendricks (2007), and Cozzi (2011) have argued that individual variation in preferences is necessary for calibrated macroeconomic models with incomplete markets to reproduce the large wealth inequality observed in the data.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…22 In Krueger, Mitman and Perri (2016), we argue that it is the latter feature (the wealth holdings of the wealth-poor) that is responsible for the finding that in our benchmark model the decline in aggregate consumption in the Great Recession is significantly more pronounced than in the original Krusell and Smith (1998) model, which in turn approximates the aggregate consumption dynamics in a representative agent model quite closely. …”
Section: Wealth Inequality In the Benchmark Economymentioning
confidence: 50%
“…20 In our benchmark model instead, dispersion in wealth is driven by uninsurable (because of incomplete markets) idiosyncratic unemployment and income shocks and preference heterogeneity, as already proposed by Krusell and Smith (1998), and further analysed by Hendricks (2007) and Carroll et al (2015). These features interact with a rudimentary life cycle structure and a publicly provided unemployment insurance system.…”
Section: Wealth Inequality In the Benchmark Economymentioning
confidence: 93%
See 1 more Smart Citation