2013
DOI: 10.3368/jhr.48.1.198
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Incorporating Employee Heterogeneity into Default Rules for Retirement Plan Selection

Abstract: The Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, part of a consortium that includes parallel centers at the University of Michigan and the National Bureau of Economic Research, was established in 1998 through a grant from the Social Security Administration. The Center's mission is to produce first-class research and forge a strong link between the academic community and decision makers in the public and private sectors around an issue of critical importance to the nation's future. To achieve this mission,… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3

Citation Types

2
26
0

Year Published

2013
2013
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
2
2

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 29 publications
(28 citation statements)
references
References 35 publications
2
26
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Other researchers have shown that poorly designed defaults can reduce welfare if employees fail to later adjust the defaults to suit their needs (Choi et al 2002(Choi et al , 2004a(Choi et al , 2004bBeshears et al 2008Beshears et al , 2010a and that optimal defaults can vary depending upon participant characteristics (Carroll et al 2009;Carlin, Gervais, and Manso 2010;Goda and Manchester 2010). Our results also suggest reasons to be cautious in relying solely on defaults to influence behavior.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 47%
“…Other researchers have shown that poorly designed defaults can reduce welfare if employees fail to later adjust the defaults to suit their needs (Choi et al 2002(Choi et al , 2004a(Choi et al , 2004bBeshears et al 2008Beshears et al , 2010a and that optimal defaults can vary depending upon participant characteristics (Carroll et al 2009;Carlin, Gervais, and Manso 2010;Goda and Manchester 2010). Our results also suggest reasons to be cautious in relying solely on defaults to influence behavior.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 47%
“…They may be cognitively constrained, as evidenced by low rates of financial literacy (Lusardi and Mitchell, 2007). Many are affected by behavioral factors outside of standard models, such as procrastination or inertia (e.g., Thaler and Benartzi, 2004;Choi et al, 2004), default rules (e.g., Madrian and Shea, 2001;Beshears et al, 2009;Mitchell et al, 2009;Goda and Manchester, 2013), peers (e.g., Saez, 2002, 2003;Beshears et al, 2011), and how information is conveyed or framed (Bernheim et al, 2011;Choi et al, 2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 97%
“…Thaler and Benartzi (2004) find that, even when individuals have to choose to be part of a savings scheme, the default of 'automatically escalating' contributions leads to much higher rates of savings. Goda and Manchester (2013) show that, in a firm where the default pension scheme changes from being a defined contribution to a defined benefit (DB) pension scheme at age 45, the proportion enrolled in the DC scheme falls by 60 percentage points. On the other hand, Bronchetti et al (2013) study a randomised experiment where 10% of a tax refund is defaulted into a savings bond and find little evidence of any effect on total savings.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%