Abstract:Judicial fact discretion is defined as misrepresentation in a judge's decision of facts revealed in a trial. We identify two motivations for the exercise of such discretion: judicial policy preferences and judges' aversion to reversal on appeal when the law is unsettled. In a standard model of a tort, we show that judicial fact discretion leads to distorted incentives for taking precautions, excessive levels of bad accidents, trial outcomes unpredictable from true facts of the case, and welfare losses. It also… Show more
“…The model in this article is most closely related to two recent articles. In Gennaioli and Shleifer (2008), deference to a trial court occurs because it is implicitly assumed that an appellate court can commit to defer to a trial judge's fact finding. Since an appellate court's review occurs ex post, what is missing from that account is an explanation for why the appellate court defers when it fully understands that the trial judge has an incentive to engage in fact distortion.…”
Section: Fact Finding In the Judicial Hierarchymentioning
How much do trial judges influence the law in the United States? I analyze a model of adjudication by a trial judge who engages in fact finding before deciding a case, but whose decision may be reversed. The model makes three broad points. First, it provides an informational rationale for ex post deference to biased trial judges that does not require an ex ante commitment by an appellate court to a standard of review. Second, it shows how procedural discretion can bring biased trial judges' rulings closer to appellate doctrine despite enabling trial judges to "get their way" more often. Third, de facto law as represented by trial judges' case-by-case adjudication will differ substantially from de jure law. As long as there are not too many extremist trial judges, de facto law will reflect the predispositions of trial judges, not legal doctrine.
“…The model in this article is most closely related to two recent articles. In Gennaioli and Shleifer (2008), deference to a trial court occurs because it is implicitly assumed that an appellate court can commit to defer to a trial judge's fact finding. Since an appellate court's review occurs ex post, what is missing from that account is an explanation for why the appellate court defers when it fully understands that the trial judge has an incentive to engage in fact distortion.…”
Section: Fact Finding In the Judicial Hierarchymentioning
How much do trial judges influence the law in the United States? I analyze a model of adjudication by a trial judge who engages in fact finding before deciding a case, but whose decision may be reversed. The model makes three broad points. First, it provides an informational rationale for ex post deference to biased trial judges that does not require an ex ante commitment by an appellate court to a standard of review. Second, it shows how procedural discretion can bring biased trial judges' rulings closer to appellate doctrine despite enabling trial judges to "get their way" more often. Third, de facto law as represented by trial judges' case-by-case adjudication will differ substantially from de jure law. As long as there are not too many extremist trial judges, de facto law will reflect the predispositions of trial judges, not legal doctrine.
“…Third, it is often not 9 See esp. Gennaioli and Shleifer (2006) who construct a model for judicial fact discretion, defined as misrepresentation in a judge's decision of facts revealed in a trial. 10 Simon describes the principle of ''bounded rationality'' as follows: ''The capacity of the human mind for formulating and solving complex problems is very small compared with the size of the problems whose solution is required for objectively rational behavior in the real world-or even for a reasonable approximation to such objective rationality'' (Simon 1957: 198).…”
Bounded rationality, Judicial errors, Civil, disciplinary and penal liability, Political accountability, Criteria for decision-making under risk and uncertainty, K13, K40, J41, D8,
“…The model of biased adjudication presented here has already been used to shed new light on a variety of issues beyond contract design. Some of the research has delved into such classical law and economic topics as common law evolution (Gennaioli and Shleifer 2007;Ponzetto and Fernandez 2008), enforcement of legal rules (Gennaioli and Shleifer 2008), and regulation (Shleifer 2010). With biased courts, not only do torts and legal evolution work differently but also the properties of different interventions against market failures are affected, since the Coase theorem no longer holds.…”
I build a model where potentially biased judges verify complex states by interpreting an imperfect signal whose noise captures factual ambiguities. In a sales and a financial transaction I show that judicial biases amplify and distort factual ambiguities, creating enforcement risk. To insure against such risk, parties write simple noncontingent contracts that optimally protect the party that is most vulnerable to judicial error. These results shed light on the empirical association between law and finance and rationalize salient features of real world enforcement regimes.
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.