1995
DOI: 10.1086/452156
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Lobbying Incentives and the Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
83
0

Year Published

2001
2001
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
4
2
2
1

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 211 publications
(85 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
2
83
0
Order By: Relevance
“…And we therefore expect governments in countries with large agricultural sectors to adopt relatively adverse policies toward farming (Olson 1965, Bates 1981, Anderson 1995.…”
Section: Lobbyingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…And we therefore expect governments in countries with large agricultural sectors to adopt relatively adverse policies toward farming (Olson 1965, Bates 1981, Anderson 1995.…”
Section: Lobbyingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…1 The classic interpretation for this pattern is that, on moving from developing to industrialised countries, the farm groups, compared to the consumer and taxpayer groups, become more effective in collective action, as a consequence of the smaller farm numbers and the lower communication and transportation costs inherent in industrial development, all factors that reduce organizational costs and free rider problems for collective action (Olson, 1965). Moreover, since the per capita cost on the rest of society falls with less farmers, the opposition of taxpayers and consumers to (agricultural) subsidies decreases as the number of farmers decreases with economic development (Becker, 1983;Swinnen, 1994;Anderson 1995).…”
Section: Testable Hypotheses For Agricultural Policymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Specifically, we start by a parsimonious specification where, as structural control, we include only the level of development, gdppc, measured by the real per capita GDP taken from the World Bank, World Development Indicators, and the share of agricultural employment, emps, based on Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) data. The inclusion of the level of development allows us to control for the so-called 'development paradox' -namely the strong positive correlation between agricultural protection and per capita GDP -that represents one of the most important stylized fact of agricultural protection patterns (see Swinnen, 1994;Anderson, 1995). On the other hand, the inclusion of the agricultural employment share acts as a control for the well known idea that small groups normally receive more protection and support.…”
Section: Other Variablesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A more convincing explanation for the net taxation of agriculture relative to the industrial sector in poor countries and the opposite bias in rich countries has to do with the differing distributional effects of those interventions and of the relative costs of lobbying the government by the key interest groups (Anderson 1995). Because farmers are mainly subsisting in poor agrarian economies, their real incomes are not greatly affected by increases in farm output prices -whereas the urban population is far smaller and more easily able to organize, and food is an important part of consumer budgets.…”
Section: Policy Developments To the Mid-1980smentioning
confidence: 99%