2014
DOI: 10.1093/restud/rdu034
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Loss Aversion and Inefficient Renegotiation

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

2
72
1

Year Published

2019
2019
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 69 publications
(75 citation statements)
references
References 42 publications
2
72
1
Order By: Relevance
“…As a result, rather than negotiating, parties might in some cases just not engage in trade. Herweg and Schmidt (2012) take a somewhat different approach and propose that buyers and sellers are loss-averse, and the contract serves as a reference point for the ex post outcomes. Since a party evaluates a worse-than-contracted term (e.g., a drop in price for the seller) as a loss, parties are reluctant to compromise and renegotiate contracts optimally due to loss aversion.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As a result, rather than negotiating, parties might in some cases just not engage in trade. Herweg and Schmidt (2012) take a somewhat different approach and propose that buyers and sellers are loss-averse, and the contract serves as a reference point for the ex post outcomes. Since a party evaluates a worse-than-contracted term (e.g., a drop in price for the seller) as a loss, parties are reluctant to compromise and renegotiate contracts optimally due to loss aversion.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, as noted in Section 3, if the L H = 1 outcome in (53) is strictly superior to specific performance, then the first inequality in (27) holds. Hence by (27), (20) does indeed hold.…”
Section: More General Contractsmentioning
confidence: 83%
“…Thus (27) guarantees that, whenever "efficient trade" is strictly superior to specific performance, (20) holds. Note that (27) is automatically satisfied if is close to (and certainly if r = r ).…”
Section: Asset Ownership and Outside Optionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations