2014
DOI: 10.1007/s11856-014-1148-2
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Majority Dynamics and the Retention of Information

Abstract: We consider a group of agents connected by a social network who participate in majority dynamics: each agent starts with an opinion in {-1,+1} and repeatedly updates it to match the opinion of the majority of its neighbors. We assume that one of {-1,+1} is the "correct" opinion S, and consider a setting in which the initial opinions are independent conditioned on S, and biased towards it. They hence contain enough information to reconstruct S with high probability. We ask whether it is still possible to reco… Show more

Help me understand this report
View preprint versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
32
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 33 publications
(33 citation statements)
references
References 21 publications
1
32
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In Section 3.1 we prove that the continuum Schelling model describes the discrete Schelling model well for small times and large w. In Section 3.2 we conclude the proof of the scaling limit result for the one-dimensional Schelling model. We also prove (proceeding similarly as in [TT14]) that the opinion of each node converges a.s. for any N ∈ N and M ≥ 2, and we include a lemma which might be related to the typical cluster size for the limiting opinions in higher dimensions. We conclude the paper with a list of open questions in Section 4.…”
Section: Overviewmentioning
confidence: 63%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In Section 3.1 we prove that the continuum Schelling model describes the discrete Schelling model well for small times and large w. In Section 3.2 we conclude the proof of the scaling limit result for the one-dimensional Schelling model. We also prove (proceeding similarly as in [TT14]) that the opinion of each node converges a.s. for any N ∈ N and M ≥ 2, and we include a lemma which might be related to the typical cluster size for the limiting opinions in higher dimensions. We conclude the paper with a list of open questions in Section 4.…”
Section: Overviewmentioning
confidence: 63%
“…Choose the w ij 's such that (i,j)∈E w ij < ∞. The existence of appropriate w ij satisfying these properties follows by [TT14, Proposition 3.4], since the degree of each node is bounded by (2w + 1) N , and since our graph satisfies the growth criterion considered in [TT14]. For each i ∈ Z N and t ≥ 0 define J i t by J i t := j∈N(i) w ij 1 X(j,t) =X(i,t) − j∈N(i) w ij 1 X(j,t − ) =X(i,t − ) .…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…They prove that, provided the graph does not grow very fast, it presents the period-two property, that says each vertex eventually has an orbit of period at most two. In Tamuz and Tessler [18], this result is strengthened, proving that, in the asynchronous model, almost surely each vertex eventually fixates and, besides, that it changes opinion only a bounded number of times. This last result is actually combinatorial: If no two clocks ring at the same time, then, for any initial condition, each site eventually fixates.…”
Section: )mentioning
confidence: 96%
“…We remark that their proof also works for Z 2 , provided p is not close to 1 2 . As a consequence of [18], majority dynamics on Z 2 fixates. This allows us to define the limiting configuration η ∞ as the pointwise limit of η t .…”
Section: )mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Other facets of majority dynamics have been studied, such as the question of whether a bias in the initial opinions tends to be preserved by this process (Tamuz and Tessler, [15]), and the threshold of initial bias which results in consensus on infinite trees (Kanoria and Montanari, [8]). Probabilistic versions of majority dynamics have been studied on highly-structured graphs.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%