1998
DOI: 10.1108/01443589810368163
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

More on the Chicago tradition

Abstract: Offers a response to David Laidler’s article “More on Hawtrey, Harvard and Chicago”, in this issue. Asserts that the unique Chicagoan quantity‐theory of the early 1930s embodied a policy framework which left it immune from the Keynesian revolution and contained important linkages with Friedman’s views in its business‐cycle analysis and policy positions. Claims that this tradition explains why Chicago (and not Harvard) originated the monetarist counter‐revolution.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1

Citation Types

0
2
0

Year Published

1998
1998
2015
2015

Publication Types

Select...
3
2

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(2 citation statements)
references
References 9 publications
0
2
0
Order By: Relevance
“…It also stressed the need to widen the range of assets eligible for rediscount by commercial banks through the inclusion, among others, of government securities. Viner underscored the crucial connection among government spending, credit expansion, and the growth of money supply, a typical monetarist argument for fiscal deficits as an effective means to put money into circulation (Tavlas 1998a, 1998b, 2003). This focus on fiscal expenditures as an accompanying measure to open market operations was even clearer in the Harvard memorandum, which stressed the need for government to undertake a “program of public construction on a nationwide scale.” The main argument was to ensure that the money put in circulation would encourage adequate expenditures:Some people feel that an increase in means of payments would have no perceptible effect since, they say, there is plenty of money now; the real difficulty is in getting it spent.…”
Section: Campaigning For Monetary Expansionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It also stressed the need to widen the range of assets eligible for rediscount by commercial banks through the inclusion, among others, of government securities. Viner underscored the crucial connection among government spending, credit expansion, and the growth of money supply, a typical monetarist argument for fiscal deficits as an effective means to put money into circulation (Tavlas 1998a, 1998b, 2003). This focus on fiscal expenditures as an accompanying measure to open market operations was even clearer in the Harvard memorandum, which stressed the need for government to undertake a “program of public construction on a nationwide scale.” The main argument was to ensure that the money put in circulation would encourage adequate expenditures:Some people feel that an increase in means of payments would have no perceptible effect since, they say, there is plenty of money now; the real difficulty is in getting it spent.…”
Section: Campaigning For Monetary Expansionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Perhaps we have in the above character sketches, and those presented below, a clue as to why there was no distinctive, lasting "Harvard tradition", oral or otherwise, comparable, say, to the renowned Chicago tradition (see the exchanges on this subject between Laidler (1998) and Tavlas (1998), for example). Young was extremely openminded, keen to inculcate into his students the art of critical and creative thinking, and insistent that economics should be both abstract and concrete, concerned with the everchanging communal problems of economic life.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%