2008
DOI: 10.1007/s00199-008-0376-2
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Non-convex aggregate technology and optimal economic growth

Abstract: This paper examines a model of optimal growth where the aggregation of two separate well behaved and concave production technologies exhibits a basic non-convexity. First, we consider the case of strictly concave utility function: when the discount rate is either low enough or high enough, there will be one steady state equilibrium toward which the convergence of the optimal paths is monotone and asymptotic. When the discount rate is in some intermediate range, we …nd su¢ -cient conditions for having either on… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
9
0

Year Published

2011
2011
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(9 citation statements)
references
References 10 publications
0
9
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This threshold property is often associated with important economic phenomena such as history dependence and poverty traps. Dechert and Nishimura's (1983) analysis has been extended by various studies on optimal growth with nonconvexities (e.g., Majumdar and Mitra, 1982;Majumdar and Nermuth, 1982;Mitra and Ray, 1984;Kamihigashi and Roy, 2007;Hung et al, 2009). The threshold property described above is also widespread even outside the optimal growth literature, arising in a broad range of economic problems concerning, for example, optimal investment for firms (e.g, Hartl and Kort, 2004;Haunschmied, et al, 2005;Wagener, 2005), renewable resources (e.g., Wirl, 2004), political behavior (e.g, Caulkins et al, 2007), and drug control (Tragler et al, 2001;Levy et al, 2006).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This threshold property is often associated with important economic phenomena such as history dependence and poverty traps. Dechert and Nishimura's (1983) analysis has been extended by various studies on optimal growth with nonconvexities (e.g., Majumdar and Mitra, 1982;Majumdar and Nermuth, 1982;Mitra and Ray, 1984;Kamihigashi and Roy, 2007;Hung et al, 2009). The threshold property described above is also widespread even outside the optimal growth literature, arising in a broad range of economic problems concerning, for example, optimal investment for firms (e.g, Hartl and Kort, 2004;Haunschmied, et al, 2005;Wagener, 2005), renewable resources (e.g., Wirl, 2004), political behavior (e.g, Caulkins et al, 2007), and drug control (Tragler et al, 2001;Levy et al, 2006).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Indeed, in order to analyse equilibria and cycles in economic growth, previous literature shows that a model must assume a concave-convex production function (Skiba, 1978; Askenazy and Le Van, 1999; Hung et al ., 2009). In this line, in what follows we model an augmented convex-concave production function to analyse and understand the impact on growth dynamics of productive capacity (capacity utilization) and technological inefficiencies.…”
Section: Model Setupmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In [12], the authors use linear functions to approximate real-world ones. Despite the fact that there exist many real-world processing functions, which are concave [8,11], approximating a function by a concave piecewise linear one is always at least as good as an approximation by a linear function (see Example 2 below). Furthermore, the authors of [12] prove the NP-hardness of their problem using a reduction from the cumulative problem.…”
Section: Properties and Remarksmentioning
confidence: 99%