2020
DOI: 10.3982/qe865
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

On households and unemployment insurance

Abstract: We study unemployment insurance in a framework where the main source of heterogeneity among agents is the type of household they live in: some agents live alone while others live with their spouses as a family. Our exercise is motivated by the fact that married individuals can rely on spousal income to smooth labor market shocks, while singles cannot. We extend a version of the standard incompletemarkets model to include two-agent households and calibrate it to the US economy with special emphasis on matching … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2

Citation Types

0
2
0

Year Published

2021
2021
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
1
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(2 citation statements)
references
References 55 publications
0
2
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Foged (2016), Braun et al (2021), andAverkamp et al (2024) show how the rational decisions of households can magnify gender discrepancies in pay, even when differences in most payrelated attributes have become minimal. 3 Our analysis aligns with the latter approach, providing a rationale for the gender gap in job satisfaction through the lens of rational 3 In a broader context, considering labor-supply decisions in dual-earner households as interdependent and collective choices of household members has advanced our understandings of consumption insurance against wage shocks (e.g., Autor et al, 2019;Blundell et al, 2016;Wu & Krueger, 2021), the intertemporal elasticity of labor supply (e.g., Bredemeier et al, 2019Bredemeier et al, , 2023, the determinants of female labor supply (e.g., Bick, 2016;Bick & Fuchs-Schündeln, 2017Bredemeier & Jüßen, 2013;Guner et al, 2012aGuner et al, , 2012b, unemployment insurance (e.g., Choi & Valladares-Esteban, 2020;Ortigueira & Siassi, 2013), and pension systems (e.g., Groneck & Wallenius, 2020;Nishiyama, 2019). Empirical evidence for the collective approach to modeling labor supply is provided by, e.g., Cherchye et al (2012) and Donni and Moreau (2007).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Foged (2016), Braun et al (2021), andAverkamp et al (2024) show how the rational decisions of households can magnify gender discrepancies in pay, even when differences in most payrelated attributes have become minimal. 3 Our analysis aligns with the latter approach, providing a rationale for the gender gap in job satisfaction through the lens of rational 3 In a broader context, considering labor-supply decisions in dual-earner households as interdependent and collective choices of household members has advanced our understandings of consumption insurance against wage shocks (e.g., Autor et al, 2019;Blundell et al, 2016;Wu & Krueger, 2021), the intertemporal elasticity of labor supply (e.g., Bredemeier et al, 2019Bredemeier et al, , 2023, the determinants of female labor supply (e.g., Bick, 2016;Bick & Fuchs-Schündeln, 2017Bredemeier & Jüßen, 2013;Guner et al, 2012aGuner et al, , 2012b, unemployment insurance (e.g., Choi & Valladares-Esteban, 2020;Ortigueira & Siassi, 2013), and pension systems (e.g., Groneck & Wallenius, 2020;Nishiyama, 2019). Empirical evidence for the collective approach to modeling labor supply is provided by, e.g., Cherchye et al (2012) and Donni and Moreau (2007).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This observation is relevant for the debate on how the optimal level of public insurance (e.g., unemployment benefits) depends on the self-insurance value. (Choi and Valladares-Esteban, 2020) Next we study the individual welfare effects of a significant but transitory drop in housing prices. We find that particularly single women, regardless of whether they own or rent a property, are most likely to incur welfare costs of such sudden changes in housing value.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%