1982
DOI: 10.2307/2526438
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Optimal Decision Rules in Uncertain Dichotomous Choice Situations

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

2
171
1

Year Published

1984
1984
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 262 publications
(174 citation statements)
references
References 4 publications
2
171
1
Order By: Relevance
“…When resolving a disagreement, the arbitrator would have to compare their own decision and confidence with those of their partner. Importantly, to make the most accurate judgments, the weight assigned to each member should be informed by the reliability of their individual responses (27,28). To learn this information, the arbitrator must dynamically track the history of trial outcomes (29).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…When resolving a disagreement, the arbitrator would have to compare their own decision and confidence with those of their partner. Importantly, to make the most accurate judgments, the weight assigned to each member should be informed by the reliability of their individual responses (27,28). To learn this information, the arbitrator must dynamically track the history of trial outcomes (29).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Lastly, a wealth of research on "homophily" in human social networks (39) suggests that our tendency for associating and bonding with similar others may exploit the benefits of an equality bias. However, when a wide competence gap separates group members, the normative strategy requires that each opinion is weighted by its reliability (28). In such situations, an equality bias can be damaging for the group.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(See Gelfand and Solomon, 1973;Gillispie, 1972;Black, 1958;Grainger, 1956;Barry, 1969;Baker, 1967Baker, , 1975. See also recent extensions by Gelfand and Solomon, 1974, 1977Grofman, 1978Grofman, , 1979Grofman, , 1980aKlevorick and Rothschild, 1978;Nagel and Neef, 1975;Grofman, Owen and Feld, 1982;Grofman, Feld and Owen, 1984 forthcoming;Grofman and Owen, 1984 forthcoming;Nitzan and Paroush, 1982;Miller, 1980;and Pinkham and Urken, 1981). 3.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The nonasymptotic part of Condorcet's statement is also not always valid (Nitzan and Paroush 1982;Ben-Yashar and Paroush 2000). For instance, Ben-Yashar and Paroush (2000) calculated that the nonasymptotic part of Condorcet's statement is valid if the competence vector is (0.8, 0.7, 0.7), in which case the simple majority rule yields a probability 0.826 of correct choice.…”
Section: Introduction and Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%