2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.01.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Optimal long-run inflation with occasionally binding financial constraints

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

0
2
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(2 citation statements)
references
References 61 publications
0
2
0
Order By: Relevance
“…There are two common approaches to this method: first, to add the penalty term to the policymaker's welfare criterion (see Woodford, 2003), Giannoni and Woodford (2003), Levine et al (2008bLevine et al ( , 2012, Giannoni (2014)); second, to add the penalty term to the agents' welfare criteria in the model (see Den Haan and Wind (2012), Abo-Zaid (2015), Karmakar (2016)). The general idea is that instead of truncating the state space of the model at the constraint, we introduce a welfare penalty if the constraint is violated; this penalty acts as a constraint while maintaining differentiability of the policy functions.…”
Section: The Zlb Constraint Through a Penalty Functionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There are two common approaches to this method: first, to add the penalty term to the policymaker's welfare criterion (see Woodford, 2003), Giannoni and Woodford (2003), Levine et al (2008bLevine et al ( , 2012, Giannoni (2014)); second, to add the penalty term to the agents' welfare criteria in the model (see Den Haan and Wind (2012), Abo-Zaid (2015), Karmakar (2016)). The general idea is that instead of truncating the state space of the model at the constraint, we introduce a welfare penalty if the constraint is violated; this penalty acts as a constraint while maintaining differentiability of the policy functions.…”
Section: The Zlb Constraint Through a Penalty Functionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A negative shock to asset liquidity or firms' collateral constraint can cause aggregate investment, employment and consumption to collapse with output (Shi, ). In addition, Abo‐Zaid () concludes, using U.S. data in a New Keynesian model with collateral constraint, that long‐run inflation is around 1.5% when the economy faces a total factor productivity (TFP) shock and about 2.5% when the economy is hit by mark‐up shocks.…”
Section: Interlink Between Monetary and Macroprudential Policiesmentioning
confidence: 99%