2012
DOI: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.03.011
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Optimal tax-timing and asset allocation when tax rebates on capital losses are limited

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
13
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(14 citation statements)
references
References 53 publications
0
13
1
Order By: Relevance
“…In contrast to the existing literature (e.g., Constantinides 1984;Dammon and Spatt 1996;Ehling et al 2010;Marekwica 2012), we find that it may be optimal for investors to defer not only short-term losses but also large long-term gains and long-term losses. Intuitively, different from what is assumed in the existing literature, the higher short-term rates apply to both long-term and short-term losses under the current law.…”
contrasting
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In contrast to the existing literature (e.g., Constantinides 1984;Dammon and Spatt 1996;Ehling et al 2010;Marekwica 2012), we find that it may be optimal for investors to defer not only short-term losses but also large long-term gains and long-term losses. Intuitively, different from what is assumed in the existing literature, the higher short-term rates apply to both long-term and short-term losses under the current law.…”
contrasting
confidence: 99%
“…3 For example, Cadenillas and Pliska (1999), Dammon, Spatt, and Zhang (2004), Gallmeyer, Kaniel, and Tompaidis (2006), Ben Tahar, Soner, and Touzi (2010), Ehling et al (2010), Marekwica (2012), and Fischer and Gallmeyer (2012). 4 As shown in DeMiguel and Uppal (2005), an investor rarely has more than one cost basis, and as shown in the Appendix, the certainty equivalent wealth loss from following a single-basis strategy (which is a feasible, but suboptimal strategy in our model) is almost negligible (to keep a single basis, one needs to liquidate the entire position before any additional purchases can be made).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Equation 22 simply guarantees for every investor that the bond does not dominate each stock from a post-tax perspective. Equation 23, that each stock price plus dividends can fall, is not necessary to rule out post-tax arbitrage, but greatly simplifies the arguments.…”
Section: Remark 3 (Extension To More General Price Systems)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For a study of portfolio choice with no wash sales, see Jensen and Marekwica [21]. The portfolio choice impact of the limited use of capital losses is studied in a single stock setting by Marekwica [22] and a multiple stock setting by Ehling et al [13].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While the impact of the opportunity to invest in a tax-deferred account has been extensively studied Sialm, 1998, 2003;Dammon et al, 2004;Poterba et al, 2004;Garlappi and Huang, 2006;Huang, 2008;Gomes et al, 2009;Zhou, 2009), only limited guidance is available to investors who face tax systems where capital gains and losses are subject to different tax treatments. In a single taxable account setting, Marekwica (2012) and Ehling et al (2015) argue that a differential tax treatment of capital gains and losses can have a large impact on optimal portfolio choice.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%